Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium modeling (abbreviated DSGE or sometimes SDGE or DGE) is a branch of applied general equilibrium theory that is influential in contemporary macroeconomics. The DSGE methodology attempts to explain aggregate economic phenomena, such as economic growth, business cycles, and the effects of monetary and fiscal policy, on the basis of macroeconomic models derived from microeconomic principles. One of the main reasons macroeconomists seek to build microfounded models is that, unlike more traditional macroeconometric forecasting models, microfounded models should not, in principle, be vulnerable to the Lucas critique. Furthermore, since the microfoundations are based on the preferences of the decision-makers in the model, DSGE models feature a natural benchmark for evaluating the welfare effects of policy changes (for discussion of both points, see Woodford, 2003, pp. 11-12 and Tovar, 2008, pp. 15-16).

Contents

Structure of DSGE models

Like other general equilibrium models, DSGE models aim to describe the behavior of the economy as a whole by analyzing the interaction of many microeconomic decisions. The decisions considered in most DSGE models correspond to some of the main quantities studied in macroeconomics, such as consumption, saving, investment, and labor supply and labor demand. The decision-makers in the model, often called 'agents', may include households, business firms, and possibly others, such as governments or central banks.

Furthermore, as their name indicates, DSGE models are dynamic, studying how the economy evolves over time. They are also stochastic, taking into account the fact that the economy is affected by random shocks such as technological change, fluctuations in the price of oil, or changes in macroeconomic policy-making. This contrasts with the static models studied in Walrasian general equilibrium theory, applied general equilibrium models and some computable general equilibrium models.

For a coherent description of the macroeconomy, DSGE models must spell out the following economic 'ingredients'.

  • Preferences: the objectives of the agents in the economy must be specified. For example, households might be assumed to maximize a utility function over consumption and labor effort. Firms might be assumed to maximize profits.
  • Technology: the productive capacity of the agents in the economy must be specified. For example, firms might be assumed to have a production function, specifying the amount of goods produced, depending on the amount of labor and capital they employ. Technological constraints on agents' decisions might also include costs of adjusting their capital stocks, their employment relations, or the prices of their products.
  • Institutional framework: the institutional constraints governing economic interactions must be specified. In many DSGE models, this might just mean that agents must obey some exogenously imposed budget constraints, and that prices are assumed to adjust until markets clear. It might also mean specifying the rules of monetary and fiscal policy, or even how policy rules and budget constraints change depending on a political process.

Traditional macroeconometric forecasting models used by central banks in the 1970s, and even today, estimated the dynamic correlations between prices and quantities in different sectors of the economy, and often included thousands of variables. Since DSGE models start from microeconomic principles of constrained decision-making, instead of just taking as given observed correlations, they are technically more difficult to solve and analyze. Therefore they usually abstract from so many sectoral details, and include far fewer variables: just a few variables in theoretical DSGE papers, or on the order of a hundred variables in the experimental DSGE forecasting models now being constructed by central banks. What DSGE models give up in sectoral detail, they attempt to make up in logical consistency.

Advantages and disadvantages of DSGE modeling

By specifying preferences (what the agents want), technology (what the agents can produce), and institutions (the way they interact), it is possible (in principle, though challenging in practice) to solve the DSGE model to predict what is actually produced, traded, and consumed, and how these variables evolve over time in response to various shocks. In principle, it is also possible to make predictions about the effects of changing the institutional framework.

In contrast, as Robert Lucas pointed out, such a prediction is unlikely to be valid in traditional macroeconometric forecasting models, since those models are based on observed past correlations between macroeconomic variables. These correlations can be expected to change when new policies are introduced, invalidating predictions based on past observations.

Given the difficulty of constructing accurate DSGE models, most central banks still rely on traditional macroeconometric models for short-term forecasting. However, the effects of alternative policies are increasingly studied using DSGE methods. Since DSGE models are constructed on the basis of assumptions about agents' preferences, it is possible to ask whether the policies considered are Pareto optimal, or how well they satisfy some other social welfare criterion derived from preferences (Woodford, 2003, p. 12).

Schools of DSGE modeling

At present two competing schools of thought form the bulk of DSGE modeling.

  • Real business cycle (RBC) theory builds on the neoclassical growth model, under the assumption of flexible prices, to study how real shocks to the economy might cause business cycle fluctuations. The paper of Kydland and Prescott (1982) is often considered the starting point of RBC theory and of DSGE modeling in general.[1] The RBC point of view is surveyed in Cooley (1995).
  • New-Keynesian DSGE models build on a structure similar to RBC models, but instead assume that prices are set by monopolistically competitive firms, and cannot be instantaneously and costlessly adjusted. The paper that first introduced this framework was Rotemberg and Woodford (1997). Introductory and advanced textbook presentations are given by Galí (2008) and Woodford (2003). Monetary policy implications are surveyed by Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (1999).

Example

The European Central Bank (ECB) has developed a DSGE model, often called the Smets-Wouters model, which it uses to analyze the economy of the Eurozone as a whole (in other words, the model does not analyze individual European countries separately). The model is intended as an alternative to the Area-Wide Model (AWM), a more traditional empirical forecasting model which the ECB has been using for several years. The ECB webpage that describes the Smets-Wouters model also discusses the advantages of building a DSGE model instead of relying on more traditional methods.

The equations in the Smets-Wouters model describe the choices of three types of decision makers: households, who choose how much to work, to consume, and to invest; firms, which choose how much labor and capital to employ; and the central bank, which controls monetary policy. The parameters in the equations were estimated using Bayesian statistical techniques so that the model approximately describes the dynamics of GDP, consumption, investment, prices, wages, employment, and interest rates in the Eurozone economy. In order to accurately reproduce the sluggish behavior of some of these variables, the model incorporates several types of frictions that slow down adjustment to shocks, including sticky prices and wages, and adjustment costs in investment.

Controversy

Willem Buiter has argued that DSGE models rely excessively on an assumption of complete markets, and are unable to describe the highly nonlinear dynamics of economic fluctuations, making training in 'state-of-the-art' macroeconomic modeling "a privately and socially costly waste of time and resources".[2]

N. Gregory Mankiw, regarded as one of the founders of New Keynesian DSGE modeling, has also argued that

'New classical and new Keynesian research has had little impact on practical macroeconomists who are charged with ... policy. ... From the standpoint of macroeconomic engineering, the work of the past several decades looks like an unfortunate wrong turn.'[3]

Michael Woodford, replying to Mankiw, argues that DSGE models are commonly used by central banks today, and have strongly influenced policy makers like Ben Bernanke. However, he argues that what is learned from DSGE models is not so different from traditional Keynesian analysis:

'It is true that the modeling efforts of many policy institutions can reasonably be seen as an evolutionary development within the macroeconomic modeling program of the postwar Keynesians; thus if one expected, with the early New Classicals, that adoption of the new tools would require building anew from the ground up, one might conclude that the new tools have not been put to use. But in fact they have been put to use, only not with such radical consequences as had once been expected.'[4]

Narayana Kocherlakota, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, acknowledges that DSGE models were not very useful for analyzing the financial crisis of 2007-2010.[5] Nonetheless, he argues that the applicability of these models is improving, and that there is growing consensus among macroeconomists that DSGE models need to incorporate both price stickiness and financial market frictions.

The United States Congress hosted hearings on macroeconomic modeling methods on July 20, 2010, to investigate why macroeconomists failed to foresee the Financial crisis of 2007-2010. Robert Solow blasted DSGE models currently in use:

'I do not think that the currently popular DSGE models pass the smell test. They take it for granted that the whole economy can be thought about as if it were a single, consistent person or dynasty carrying out a rationally designed, long-term plan, occasionally disturbed by unexpected shocks, but adapting to them in a rational, consistent way... The protagonists of this idea make a claim to respectability by asserting that it is founded on what we know about microeconomic behavior, but I think that this claim is generally phony. The advocates no doubt believe what they say, but they seem to have stopped sniffing or to have lost their sense of smell altogether.'[6]

V.V. Chari pointed out, however, that state-of-the-art DSGE models are more sophisticated than their critics suppose:

'The models have all kinds of heterogeneity in behavior and decisions... people's objectives differ, they differ by age, by information, by the history of their past experiences. '

Chari also argued that current DSGE models frequently incorporate frictional unemployment, financial market imperfections, and sticky prices and wages, and therefore imply that the macroeconomy behaves in a suboptimal way which monetary and fiscal policy may be able to improve.[7]

Commenting on the Congressional session, The Economist asked whether Agent based models might better predict financial crises than DSGE models.[8]

Notes

  1. ^ Kydland, F.E.; Prescott, E.C. (1982), "Time to build and aggregate fluctuations", Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 50 (6): 1345–1370, http://web.mit.edu/dancao/OldFiles/Public/Network%20Idea/Time%20to%20Build%20and%20Aggregate%20Fluctuation.pdf, retrieved 2010-07-23 
  2. ^ Buiter, Willem (2009-03-03). "The unfortunate uselessness of most ’state of the art’ academic monetary economics" (HTML). ft.com/maverecon. Financial Times. http://blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2009/03/the-unfortunate-uselessness-of-most-state-of-the-art-academic-monetary-economics/. Retrieved 2010-07-23. 
  3. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2006), "The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer", The Journal of Economic Perspectives 20 (4): 29–46, http://www.economics.harvard.edu/files/faculty/40_Macroeconomist_as_Scientist.pdf, retrieved 2010-07-23 
  4. ^ Woodford, Michael (2008-01-04), "Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of a New Synthesis", annual meeting of the American Economics Association., http://www.columbia.edu/~mw2230/Convergence_AEJ.pdf 
  5. ^ Kocherlakota, Narayana (May 2010). "Modern Macroeconomic Models as Tools for Economic Policy" (HTML). Banking and Policy Issues Magazine. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. http://www.minneapolisfed.org/publications_papers/pub_display.cfm?id=4428. Retrieved 2010-07-23. 
  6. ^ Prepared Statement of Robert Solow, Professor Emeritus, MIT, to the House Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight: “Building a Science of Economics for the Real World,” July 20, 2010
  7. ^ Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, U.S. House of Representatives, V.V. Chari, Univ. of Minnesota and Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis” July 20, 2010
  8. ^ Agents of change, The Economist, July 22, 2010.

References

  • Bank of England (2005), 'The Bank of England quarterly model': http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/other/beqm/index.htm (See especially Chapters 1 and 3.)
  • European Central Bank: The Smets-Wouters (2003) model
  • Fabio Canova (2007), Methods for Applied Macroeconomic Research. Princeton University Press, ISBN 0-691-11504-4.
  • Richard Clarida, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler (1999), 'The science of monetary policy: a New-Keynesian perspective.' Journal of Economic Literature 37, pp. 1661-707.
  • Thomas Cooley, ed., (1995), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton University Press, ISBN 069104323X.
  • DeJong, D. N. with C. Dave (2007), Structural Macroeconometrics. Princeton University Press, ISBN 0691126488.
  • Galí, Jordi (2008), Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle. Princeton University Press, ISBN 9780691133164.
  • Robert E. Lucas, Jr. (1976), 'Econometric policy evaluation: a critique.' Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy' 1, pp. 19-46.
  • Julio Rotemberg and Michael Woodford (1997), 'An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy.' NBER Macroeconomics Annual 12, pp. 297-346.
  • Camilo Tovar (2008), 'DSGE models and central banks', Bank for International Settlements working paper #258.
  • Michael Woodford (2003), Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton University Press, ISBN 0691010498.
  • Narayana Kocherlakota (2010), 'Modern Macroeconomic Models as Tools for Economic Policy.' The Region, May 2010.
  • Argia Sbordone, Andrea Tambalotti, Krishna Rao, and Kieran Walsh (2010), 'Policy analysis using DSGE models: an introduction'. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 16 (2).

See also

External links

  • Society for Economic Dynamics - Website of the Society for Economic Dynamics, dedicated to advances in DSGE modeling
  • DSGE-NET - International Network for DSGE modeling, monetary and fiscal policy
  • DYNARE - software for DSGE modeling

Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать курсовую

Look at other dictionaries:

  • General equilibrium — theory is a branch of theoretical microeconomics. It seeks to explain the behavior of supply, demand and prices in a whole economy with several or many markets. It is often assumed that agents are price takers and in that setting two common… …   Wikipedia

  • Computable general equilibrium — (CGE) models are a class of economic models that use actual economic data to estimate how an economy might react to changes in policy, technology or other external factors. CGE models are also referred to as AGE (applied general equilibrium)… …   Wikipedia

  • Intertemporal equilibrium — is a notion of economic equilibrium conceived over many periods of time. The term has a different meaning in contemporary macroeconomics from its earlier meaning in Austrian economics. Meaning in contemporary macroeconomicsIn New Classical or New …   Wikipedia

  • Macroeconomic model — A macroeconomic model is an analytical tool designed to describe the operation of the economy of a country or a region. These models are usually designed to examine the dynamics of aggregate quantities such as the total amount of goods and… …   Wikipedia

  • Mathematical optimization — For other uses, see Optimization (disambiguation). The maximum of a paraboloid (red dot) In mathematics, computational science, or management science, mathematical optimization (alternatively, optimization or mathematical programming) refers to… …   Wikipedia

  • Model (macroeconomics) — A model in macroeconomics is a logical, mathematical, and/or computational framework designed to describe the operation of a national or regional economy, and especially the dynamics of aggregate quantities such as the total amount of goods and… …   Wikipedia

  • New Keynesian economics — Not to be confused with Neo Keynesian economics. Economics …   Wikipedia

  • Nueva Economía Keynesiana — No debe confundirse con neokeynesianismo. La Nueva economía keynesiana o Nuevo keynesianismo es una escuela del pensamiento económico que busca proveer fundaciones microeconómicas a la economía keynesiana. Se desarrolló como respuestas a las… …   Wikipedia Español

  • Critique De Lucas — La critique de Lucas, formulée par Robert Lucas Jr en 1976[1] a apporté un changement important dans la façon dont les modèles économétriques sont construits. Lucas a étudié la façon dont les agents forment leurs anticipations de l avenir, qui… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Critique de Lucas — La critique de Lucas, formulée par Robert Lucas Jr en 1976[1] a apporté un changement important dans la façon dont les modèles économétriques sont construits. Lucas a étudié la façon dont les agents forment leurs anticipations de l avenir, qui… …   Wikipédia en Français

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”