Macroeconomic model

Macroeconomic model
Example of a Macroeconomics Model

A macroeconomic model is an analytical tool designed to describe the operation of the economy of a country or a region. These models are usually designed to examine the dynamics of aggregate quantities such as the total amount of goods and services produced, total income earned, the level of employment of productive resources, and the level of prices.

Macroeconomic models may be logical, mathematical, and/or computational; the different types of macroeconomic models serve different purposes and have different advantages and disadvantages. Macroeconomics models may be used to clarify and illustrate basic theoretical principles; they may be used to test, compare, and quantify different macroeconomic theories; they may be used to produce "what if" scenarios (usually to predict the effects of changes in monetary, fiscal, or other macroeconomic policies); and they may be used to generate economic forecasts. Thus, macroeconomic models are widely used in academia, teaching and research, and are also widely used by international organizations, national governments and larger corporations, as well as by economics consultants and think tanks.

Contents

Types of macroeconomic models

Simple theoretical models

Simple text book descriptions of the macroeconomy involving a small number of equations or diagrams are often called ‘models’. Examples include the IS-LM model and Mundell-Fleming model of Keynesian macroeconomics, and the Solow model of neoclassical growth theory. These models share several features. They are based on a few equations involving a few variables, which can often be explained with simple diagrams.[1] Many of these models are static, but some are dynamic, describing the economy over many time periods. The variables that appear in these models often represent macroeconomic aggregates (such as GDP or total employment) rather than individual choice variables, and while the equations relating these variables are intended to describe economic decisions, they are not usually derived directly by aggregating models of individual choices. They are simple enough to be used as illustrations of theoretical points in introductory explanations of macroeconomic ideas; but therefore quantitative application to forecasting, testing, or policy evaluation is usually impossible without substantially augmenting the structure of the model.

Empirical forecasting models

In the 1940s and 1950s, as governments began accumulating national income and product accounting data, economists set out to construct quantitative models to describe the dynamics observed in the data.[2] These models estimated the relations between different macroeconomic variables using (mostly linear) time series analysis. Like the simpler theoretical models, these empirical models described relations between aggregate quantities, but many addressed a much finer level of detail (for example, studying the relations between output, employment, investment, and other variables in many different industries). Thus, these models grew to include hundreds or thousands of equations describing the evolution of hundreds or thousands of prices and quantities over time, making computers essential for their solution. While the choice of which variables to include in each equation was partly guided by economic theory (for example, including past income as a determinant of consumption, as suggested by the theory of adaptive expectations), variable inclusion was mostly determined on purely empirical grounds.

Dutch economist Jan Tinbergen developed the first comprehensive national model, which he built for the Netherlands in 1936. He later applied the same modeling structure to the economies of the United States and the United Kingdom.[2] The first global macroeconomic model, Wharton Econometric Forecasting Associates' LINK project, was initiated by Lawrence Klein. The model was cited in 1980 when Klein, like Tinbergen before him, won the Nobel Prize. Large-scale empirical models of this type, including the Wharton model, are still in use today, especially for forecasting purposes.[3][4][5]

The Lucas critique of empirical forecasting models

Econometric studies in the first part of the 20th century showed a negative correlation between inflation and unemployment called the Phillips curve.[6] Empirical macroeconomic forecasting models, being based on roughly the same data, had similar implications: they suggested that unemployment could be permanently lowered by permanently increasing inflation. However, in 1968, Milton Friedman[7] and Edmund Phelps[8] argued that this apparent tradeoff was illusory. They claimed that the historical relation between inflation and unemployment was due to the fact that past inflationary episodes had been largely unexpected. They argued that if monetary authorities permanently raised the inflation rate, workers and firms would eventually come to understand this, at which point the economy would return to its previous, higher level of unemployment, but now with higher inflation too. The stagflation of the 1970s appeared to bear out their prediction.[9]

In 1976, Robert Lucas, Jr., published an influential paper[10] arguing that the failure of the Phillips curve in the 1970s was just one example of a general problem with empirical forecasting models. He pointed out that such models are derived from observed relationships between various macroeconomic quantities over time, and that these relations differ depending on what macroeconomic policy regime is in place. In the context of the Phillips curve, this means that the relation between inflation and unemployment observed in an economy where inflation has usually been low in the past would differ from the relation observed in an economy where inflation has been high.[11] Furthermore, this means one cannot predict the effects of a new policy regime using an empirical forecasting model based on data from previous periods when that policy regime was not in place. Lucas argued that economists would remain unable to predict the effects of new policies unless they built models based on economic fundamentals (like preferences, technology, and budget constraints) that should be unaffected by policy changes.

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models

Partly as a response to the Lucas critique, economists of the 1980s and 1990s began to construct microfounded[12] macroeconomic models based on rational choice, which have come to be called dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models. These models begin by specifying the set of agents active in the economy, such as households, firms, and governments in one or more countries, as well as the preferences, technology, and budget constraint of each one. Each agent is assumed to make an optimal choice, taking into account prices and the strategies of other agents, both in the current period and in the future. Summing up the decisions of the different types of agents, it is possible to find the prices that equate supply with demand in every market. Thus these models embody a type of equilibrium self-consistency: agents choose optimally given the prices, while prices must be consistent with agents’ supplies and demands.

DSGE models often assume that all agents of a given type are identical (i.e. there is a ‘representative household’ and a ‘representative firm’) and can perform perfect calculations that forecast the future correctly on average (which is called rational expectations). However, these are only simplifying assumptions, and are not essential for the DSGE methodology; many DSGE studies aim for greater realism by considering heterogeneous agents[13] or various types of adaptive expectations.[14] Compared with empirical forecasting models, DSGE models typically have less variables and equations, mainly because DSGE models are harder to solve, even with the help of computers.[15] Simple theoretical DSGE models, involving only a few variables, have been used to analyze the forces that drive business cycles; this empirical work has given rise to two main competing frameworks called the real business cycle model[16][17][18] and the New Keynesian DSGE model.[19][20] More elaborate DSGE models are used to predict the effects of changes in economic policy and evaluate their impact on social welfare. However, economic forecasting is still largely based on more traditional empirical models, which are still widely believed to achieve greater accuracy in predicting the impact of economic disturbances over time.

DSGE versus CGE models

A closely related methodology that pre-dates DSGE modeling is computable general equilibrium (CGE) modeling. Like DSGE models, CGE models are often microfounded on assumptions about preferences, technology, and budget constraints. However, CGE models focus mostly on long-run relationships, making them most suited to studying the long-run impact of permanent policies like the tax system or the openness of the economy to international trade.[21][22] DSGE models instead emphasize the dynamics of the economy over time (often at a quarterly frequency), making them suited for studying business cycles and the cyclical effects of monetary and fiscal policy.

Agent-based computational macroeconomic models

Another modeling methodology which has developed at the same time as DSGE models is Agent-based computational economics (ACE), which is a variety of Agent-based modeling.[23] Like the DSGE methodology, ACE seeks to break down aggregate macroeconomic relationships into microeconomic decisions of individual agents. ACE models also begin by defining the set of agents that make up the economy, and specify the types of interactions individual agents can have with each other or with the market as a whole. Instead of defining the preferences of those agents, ACE models often jump directly to specifying their strategies. Or sometimes, preferences are specified, together with an initial strategy and a learning rule whereby the strategy is adjusted according to its past success.[24] Given these strategies, the interaction of large numbers of individual agents (who may be very heterogeneous) can be simulated on a computer, and then the aggregate, macroeconomic relationships that arise from those individual actions can be studied.

Strengths and weaknesses of DSGE and ACE models

DSGE and ACE models have different advantages and disadvantages due to their different underlying structures. DSGE models may exaggerate individual rationality and foresight, and understate the importance of heterogeneity, since the rational expectations, representative agent case remains the simplest and thus the most common type of DSGE model to solve. Also, unlike ACE models, it may be difficult to study local interactions between individual agents in DSGE models, which instead focus mostly on the way agents interact through aggregate prices. On the other hand, ACE models may exaggerate errors in individual decision-making, since the strategies assumed in ACE models may be very far from optimal choices unless the modeler is very careful. A related issue is that ACE models which start from strategies instead of preferences may remain vulnerable to the Lucas critique: a changed policy regime should generally give rise to changed strategies.

See also

References

  1. ^ Blanchard, Olivier (2000), Macroeconomics, 2nd ed., Chap. 3.3, p. 47. Prentice Hall, ISBN 013013306X.
  2. ^ a b Klein, Lawrence, (2004), 'The contribution of Jan Tinbergen to economic science.' De Economist, 152 (2), pp. 155-157.
  3. ^ Lawrence R. Klein, ed. (1991), Comparative Performance of US Econometric Models. Oxford University Press, ISBN 0195057724.
  4. ^ Eckstein, Otto (1983), The DRI Model of the US Economy. McGraw-Hill, DOI-10.2307/1058399, ISBN 0070189722.
  5. ^ Ronald Bodkin, Lawrence Klein, and Kanta Marwah (1991), A History of Macroeconometric Model Building. Edward Elgar.
  6. ^ Phillips, A. W. (1958), "The relationship between unemployment and the rate of change of money wages in the United Kingdom 1861-1957", Economica 25 (100): 283–299 
  7. ^ Friedman, Milton (1968), "The role of monetary policy", American Economic Review (American Economic Association) 58 (1): 1–17, JSTOR 1831652 
  8. ^ Phelps, Edmund S. (1968), "Money wage dynamics and labor market equilibrium", Journal of Political Economy 76 (4): 678–711, doi:10.1086/259438 
  9. ^ Blanchard, Olivier (2000), op. cit., Ch. 28, p. 540.
  10. ^ Lucas, Robert E., Jr. (1976), "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique", Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1: 19–46, doi:10.1016/S0167-2231(76)80003-6 
  11. ^ Blanchard, Olivier (2000), op. cit., Ch. 28, p. 542.
  12. ^ Edmund S. Phelps, ed., (1970), Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory. New York, Norton and Co. ISBN 0-393-09326-3.
  13. ^ Per Krusell and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. (1998), 'Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy.' Journal of Political Economy 106 (5), pp. 243-77.
  14. ^ George W. Evans and Seppo Honkapohja (2001), Learning and Expectations in Macroeconomics. Princeton University Press, ISBN 0-691-04921-1.
  15. ^ DeJong, D. N. with C. Dave (2007), Structural Macroeconometrics. Princeton University Press, ISBN 0691126488.
  16. ^ Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott (1982), 'Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations'. Econometrica, 50, 1345-70.
  17. ^ Thomas F. Cooley (1995), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton University Press.
  18. ^ Andrew Abel and Ben Bernanke (1995), Macroeconomics, 2nd ed., Ch. 11.1, pp. 355-362. Addison-Wesley, ISBN 0201543923.
  19. ^ Julio Rotemberg and Michael Woodford (1997), 'An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy'. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 12, pp. 297-346.
  20. ^ Woodford, Michael (2003), Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton University Press, ISBN 0691010498.
  21. ^ Shoven, John B., and John Whalley (1972), 'A general equilibrium calculation of the effects of differential taxation of income from capital in the US.' Journal of Public Economics 1, pp. 281-321.
  22. ^ Kehoe, Patrick J., and Timothy J. Kehoe (1994), 'A primer on static applied general equilibrium models'. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 18 (1).
  23. ^ Leigh Tesfatsion (2003), 'Agent-Based Computational Economics', Iowa State University Economics Working Paper #1.
  24. ^ William Brock and Cars Hommes (1997), 'A rational route to randomness.' Econometrica 65 (5), 1059-1095.

External links


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем решить контрольную работу

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Model (macroeconomics) — A model in macroeconomics is a logical, mathematical, and/or computational framework designed to describe the operation of a national or regional economy, and especially the dynamics of aggregate quantities such as the total amount of goods and… …   Wikipedia

  • Model — Contents 1 Physical 1.1 Human models 2 Nonphysical 2.1 …   Wikipedia

  • Economic model — A diagram of the IS/LM model In economics, a model is a theoretical construct that represents economic processes by a set of variables and a set of logical and/or quantitative relationships between them. The economic model is a simplified… …   Wikipedia

  • AD-AS model — The AD AS or Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply model is a macroeconomic model that explains price level and output through the relationship of aggregate demand and aggregate supply. It was first put forth by John Maynard Keynes in his work The… …   Wikipedia

  • Anglo-Saxon economy (economic model) — An Anglo Saxon economy or Anglo Saxon capitalism (so called because it is supposedly practiced in English speaking countries such as the United Kingdom, the United States, Canada, New Zealand, Australia [Mitchell 2006, p.116. Mitchell groups all… …   Wikipedia

  • Overlapping generations model — For the topic in population genetics, see Overlapping generations. An overlapping generations model, abbreviated to OLG model, is a type of economic model in which agents live a finite length of time and live long enough to endure into at least… …   Wikipedia

  • ISLM Model — A macroeconomic model that graphically represents two intersecting curves, called the IS and LM curves. The investment/saving (IS) curve is a variation of the income expenditure model incorporating market interest rates (demand for this model),… …   Investment dictionary

  • DAD-SAS model — The DAD SAS model is a macroeconomic model based on the AD AS model but that looks at the different incomes at different inflation levels. DAD curve The DAD (Dynamic aggregate demand) curve is in the long run a horizontal line called the EAD… …   Wikipedia

  • IS/LM model — The IS curve moves to the right, causing higher interest rates (i) and expansion in the real economy (real GDP, or Y). The IS/LM model (Investment Saving/Liquidity preference Money supply) is a macroeconomic tool that demonstrates the… …   Wikipedia

  • Multi-Factor Model — A financial model that employs multiple factors in its computations to explain market phenomena and/or equilibrium asset prices. The multi factor model can be used to explain either an individual security or a portfolio of securities. It will do… …   Investment dictionary

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”