Strategic dominance

Strategic dominance

In game theory, strategic dominance (commonly called simply dominance) occurs when one strategy is better than another strategy for one player, no matter how that player's opponents may play. Many simple games can be solved using dominance. The opposite, intransitivity, occurs in games where one strategy may be better or worse than another strategy for one player, depending on how the player's opponents may play.

Contents

Terminology

When a player tries to choose the "best" strategy among a multitude of options, that player may compare two strategies A and B to see which one is better. The result of the comparison is one of:

  • B dominates A: choosing B always gives at least as good an outcome as choosing A. There are 2 possibilities:
    • B strictly dominates A: choosing B always gives a better outcome than choosing A, no matter what the other player(s) do.
    • B weakly dominates A: There is at least one set of opponents' action for which B is superior, and all other sets of opponents' actions give B at least the same payoff as A.
  • B and A are intransitive: B neither dominates, nor is dominated by, A. Choosing A is better in some cases, while choosing B is better in other cases, depending on exactly how the opponent chooses to play. For example, B is "throw rock" while A is "throw scissors" in Rock, Paper, Scissors.
  • B is dominated by A: choosing B never gives a better outcome than choosing A, no matter what the other player(s) do. There are 2 possibilities:
    • B is weakly dominated by A: There is at least one set of opponents' actions for which B gives a worse outcome than A, while all other sets of opponents' actions give A at least the same payoff as B. (Strategy A weakly dominates B).
    • B is strictly dominated by A: choosing B always gives a worse outcome than choosing A, no matter what the other player(s) do. (Strategy A strictly dominates B).

This notion can be generalized beyond the comparison of two strategies.

  • Strategy B is strictly dominant if strategy B strictly dominates every other possible strategy.
  • Strategy B is weakly dominant if strategy B dominates all other strategies, but some are only weakly dominated.
  • Strategy B is strictly dominated if some other strategy exists that strictly dominates B.
  • Strategy B is weakly dominated if some other strategy exists that weakly dominates B.

Mathematical definition

For any player i, a strategy s^*\in S_i weakly dominates another strategy s^\prime\in S_i if

\forall s_{-i}\in S_{-i}\left[u_i(s^*,s_{-i})\geq u_i(s^\prime,s_{-i})\right] (With at least one s i that gives a strict inequality)

s * strictly dominates s^\prime if

\forall s_{-i}\in S_{-i}\left[u_i(s^*,s_{-i})> u_i(s^\prime,s_{-i})\right]

where S i represents the product of all strategy sets other than player i's

Dominance and Nash equilibria

C D
C 1, 1 0, 0
D 0, 0 0, 0

If a strictly dominant strategy exists for one player in a game, that player will play that strategy in each of the game's Nash equilibria. If both players have a strictly dominant strategy, the game has only one unique Nash equilibrium. However, that Nash equilibrium is not necessarily Pareto optimal, meaning that there may be non-equilibrium outcomes of the game that would be better for both players. The classic game used to illustrate this is the Prisoner's Dilemma.

Strictly dominated strategies cannot be a part of a Nash equilibrium, and as such, it is irrational for any player to play them. On the other hand, weakly dominated strategies may be part of Nash equilibria. For instance, consider the payoff matrix pictured at the right.

Strategy C weakly dominates strategy D. Consider playing C: If one's opponent plays C, one gets 1; if one's opponent plays D, one gets 0. Compare this to D, where one gets 0 regardless. Since in one case, one does better by playing C instead of D and never does worse, C weakly dominates D. Despite this, (D, D) is a Nash equilibrium. Suppose both players choose D. Neither player will do any better by unilaterally deviating—if a player switches to playing C, they will still get 0. This satisfies the requirements of a Nash equilibrium. Suppose both players choose C. Neither player will do better by unilaterally deviating—if a player switches to playing D, they will get 0. This also satisfies the requirements of a Nash equilibrium.

Iterated elimination of dominated strategies (IEDS)

The iterated elimination (or deletion) of dominated strategies is one common technique for solving games that involves iteratively removing dominated strategies. In the first step, at most one dominated strategy is removed from the strategy space of each of the players since no rational player would ever play these strategies. This results in a new, smaller game. Some strategies—that were not dominated before—may be dominated in the smaller game. The first step is repeated, creating a new even smaller game, and so on. It is possible that in any step 0 strategies may be deleted for some players. The process stops when in any round 0 strategies are deleted. This process is valid since it is assumed that rationality among players is common knowledge, that is, each player knows that the rest of the players are rational, and each player knows that the rest of the players know that he knows that the rest of the players are rational, and so on ad infinitum (see Aumann, 1976).

There are two versions of this process. One version involves only eliminating strictly dominated strategies. If, after completing this process, there is only one strategy for each player remaining, that strategy set is the unique Nash equilibrium.

Another version involves eliminating both strictly and weakly dominated strategies. If, at the end of the process, there is a single strategy for each player, this strategy set is also a Nash equilibrium. However, unlike the first process, elimination of weakly dominated strategies may eliminate some Nash equilibria. As a result, the Nash equilibrium found by eliminating weakly dominated strategies may not be the only Nash equilibrium. (In some games, if we remove weakly dominated strategies in a different order, we may end up with a different Nash equilibrium.)

In any case, if by iterated elimination of dominated strategies there is only one strategy left for each player, the game is called a dominant solvable game.

See also

References


This article incorporates material from Dominant strategy on PlanetMath, which is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share-Alike License.


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужен реферат?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Dominance — may refer to: Dominance (C++), an aspect of virtual inheritance in the C++ programming language Dominance (economics), in economics, the degree of inequality in market share distribution Strategic dominance, in game theory, when one strategy is… …   Wikipedia

  • Dominance (game theory) — In game theory, dominance (also called strategic dominance) occurs when one strategy is better than another strategy for one player, no matter how that player s opponents may play. Many simple games can be solved using dominance.The opposite,… …   Wikipedia

  • Dominance (economics) — For other uses, see Dominance. For the game theory, see Strategic dominance. Marketing Key concepts …   Wikipedia

  • Strategic management — is a field that deals with the major intended and emergent initiatives taken by general managers on behalf of owners, involving utilization of resources, to enhance the performance of firms in their external environments.[1] It entails specifying… …   Wikipedia

  • Strategic Environmental Assessment (Denmark) — The Strategic Environmental Assessment (SEA), is a process in Denmark for assessing the environmental effects of proposed government projects and programmes. Established in 1993 by an administrative order of Denmark s Prime Minister’s Office,[1]… …   Wikipedia

  • Full-spectrum dominance — is a military concept whereby a joint military structure achieves control over all elements of the battlespace using land, air, maritime and space based assets.Full spectrum dominance includes the physical battlespace; air, surface and sub… …   Wikipedia

  • Chaos Overlords: Strategic Gang Warfare — Chaos Overlords Разработчик Stick Man Games Издатель New World Computing Создатели Геймдизайнер John K. Morris …   Википедия

  • Palestine — /pal euh stuyn / for 1, 2; /pal euh steen / for 3, n. 1. Also called Holy Land. Biblical name, Canaan. an ancient country in SW Asia, on the E coast of the Mediterranean. 2. a former British mandate (1923 48) comprising part of this country,… …   Universalium

  • Shōwa period — The nihongo|Shōwa period|昭和時代|Shōwa jidai|literally period of enlightened peace , or Shōwa era, is the period of Japanese history corresponding to the reign of Emperor Shōwa (Hirohito), from December 25, 1926 to January 7, 1989. In his coronation …   Wikipedia

  • Kingdom of Bavaria — Infobox Former Country native name = Königreich Bayern conventional long name = Kingdom of Bavaria common name = Bavaria continent = Europe region = Germany country = Germany status = Member of Confederation of the Rhine (1806 13) Member of… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”