- Public goods game
The Public goods game is a standard of
experimental economics ; in the basic game subjects secretly choose how many of their private tokens to put into the public pot. Each subject keeps the tokens they do not contribute plus an even split of the tokens in the pot (researchers running the game multiply the number of tokens in the pot before it is distributed to encourage contribution).Results
The group as a whole does best when everyone contributes all of their tokens into the public pool. If everyone puts every token they start with into the pot then the group will extract the maximum total reward from the economists running the test. However, the
Nash equilibrium in this game is simply zero contributions by all; if the experiment were a purely analytical exercise ingame theory it would resolve to zero contributions because any player does better contributing zero than any other amount regardless of whatever anyone else does. (Following game theory, those who contribute nothing are called "defector s", as opposed to the contributors who are called "cooperators". The defector is also a "free rider").In fact, the Nash equilibrium is rarely seen in experiments; people do tend to add something into the pot. The actual levels of contribution found in individual subjects varies widely (anywhere from 0% to 100% of initial endowment can be chipped in - subjects are
heterogeneous ). (This conclusion and others taken from Ahn & Janssen's2003 summary cited below.)Variants
Iterated public goods games
"Repeat-play" public goods games simply involve the same group of subjects playing the basic game over a series of rounds. The typical result is a declining proportion of public contribution, from the simple game (the "One-shot" public goods game). When trusting contributors see that not everyone is giving up as much as they do they tend to reduce the amount they share with the group if the game is repeated to another round. If this is again repeated the same thing happens but from a lower base, so that the amount contributed to the pot is reduced again. However, the amount contributed to the pool rarely drops to zero when rounds of the game are iterated, because there tend to remain a hardcore of ‘givers’.
One explanation for the dropping level of contribution is
inequity aversion ; once it is realized that others are receiving a bigger share for a smaller contribution the sharing members react against the perceived injustice (even though the identity of the “free riders” are unknown, and it’s only a game). Those who contribute nothing in one round, rarely contribute something in later rounds, even after discovering that other people are.Open public goods games
If the amount contributed isn't hidden it tends to be higher. In a typical public goods game there might be six subjects contributing to the pot so concealing the level of contribution isn't difficult. In "pairwise iterations" with only two players the other player's contribution level is always known.
Public goods games with punishment
Famously, the option to punish non-contributors after a round of the public goods game is widely exercised (although costly and technically “irrational”). In most experiments this leads to greater group cooperation, and fewer defections in subsequent rounds.
Public goods games with mercy/reward
At the same time, the option to mercy/reward the contributors after a round of the public goods game is exercised also(although more costly and technically “irrational”). But without the helping of punishment mechanism in experiments, mercy/reward seems not enhance long-term group cooperation(Bin Xu, (2008)).
The multiplication factor
In order for contribution to be privately "irrational" the tokens in the pot must be multiplied by an amount smaller than the number of players and greater than 1. Other than this, the level of multiplication has little bearing on
strategy , but higher factors produce higher proportions of contribution.E.g: Isaac et al. showed that with a large group (40) and very low multiplication factor (1.03) almost no-one contributes anything after a few iterations of the game (a few still do). However, with the same size group and a 1.3 multiplication factor the average level of initial endowment contributed to the pot is around 50%.
Implications
The name of the game comes from
economist ’s definition of a “public good ”. One type of public good is a costly, "non-excludable" project that every one can benefit from, regardless of how much they contribute to create it (because no one can be excluded from using it - like street lighting). Part of the economic theory of public goods is that they would be under-provided (at a rate lower than the ‘social optimum’) because individuals had no private motive to contribute (thefree rider problem). The “public goods game” is designed to test this belief and connected theories ofsocial behaviour .Game theory
The empirical fact that subjects in most societies contribute anything at all in the simple public goods game is a challenge for
game theory to explain via a motive of total self-interest, although it can do better with the ‘punishment’ variant, or the ‘iterated’ variant; because some of the motivation to contribute is now purely “rational”, if players assume that others may act irrationally and punish them for non-contribution.Applications to sociology
The
sociological interpretation of these results emphasises group cohesion, and cultural norms to explain the "prosocial " outcomes of Public goods games.See also
*
Ultimatum game
*Trust game
*Prisoner's dilemma
*Robert Axelrod , "The Evolution of Cooperation "References
* Ahn & Janseen,
2003 , "Adaptation vs. Anticipation in Public-Good Games" [http://garnet.acns.fsu.edu/~tcarsey/talks/JanssenAhnOct1-2003-2.pdf] (This paper, from researchers at Indiana University andFlorida State University summarizes the experimental findings of earlier research before comparing theoretical models against these results.)
* Isaac, Walker, and Williams,1994 "Group Size and the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods: Experimental Evidence Utilizing Large Groups." Journal of Public Economics, 54(1)
* James Andreoni, William Harbaugh and Lise Vesterlund2003 "The Carrot or the Stick: Rewards, Punishments, and Cooperation" The American Economic Review, 93(3)(2003)pp. 893-902External links
* [http://www.univie.ac.at/virtuallabs/PublicGoods/mixed.html The evolution of strategies] in public goods games: Three interactive simulations of the spread of defection among automated players choosing between strategies. (This is a model of experimental economics, rather than an actual experiment.)
* [http://www.krannert.purdue.edu/faculty/cason/papers/intspite.pdf Voluntary Participation and Spite in Public Good Provision Experiments: An International Comparison] . This is anEconomic Science Association paper from2002 detailing the methodology and results used in an experiment comparing the performance ofJapan ese and American subjects in public goods games. They reject the hypothesis of international equality in overall efficiency::The mean contribution rate among the 60 Japanese subjects was 80%:The mean contribution rate among the 39 American subjects was 69%
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.