Nudge (book)

Nudge (book)
Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness  
Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness
Author(s) Cass Sunstein and Richard Thaler
Language English
Genre(s) Non-fiction
Publisher Yale University Press
Publication date April 8, 2008
Pages 312
ISBN 978-0-14-311526-7

Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness is a book written by Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein. The book draws on research in psychology and behavioral economics to defend libertarian paternalism and active engineering of choice architecture.[1][2][3][4]

The book received mixed reviews. The Guardian described it as "never intimidating, always amusing and elucidating: a jolly economic romp but with serious lessons within." But The Sunday Times called it a "very, very dull read" and others contended that the many policy proposals it contained became "a bit wearisome". It was named a "Best Book of the Year" by The Economist.

Contents

Summary

Human behavior

One of the main justifications for Thaler's and Sunstein's endorsement of libertarian paternalism in Nudge draws on facts of human nature and psychology. The book is critical of the homo economicus view of human beings "that each of us thinks and chooses unfailingly well, and thus fits within the textbook picture of human beings offered by economists."[5]

They cite many examples of research which raise "serious questions about the rationality of many judgments and decisions that people make".[6] They state that, unlike members of homo economicus, members of the species homo sapiens make predictable mistakes because of their use of heuristics, fallacies, and because of the way they are influenced by their social interactions.

Two systems of thought

The book describes two systems that characterize human thought. Sunstein and Thaler refer to these as the "Reflective System" and the "Automatic System".[7] The Automatic System is "rapid and is or feels instinctive, and it does not involve what we usually associate with the word thinking".[8] Instances of the Automatic System at work include smiling upon seeing a puppy, getting nervous while experiencing air turbulence, and ducking when a ball is thrown at you.

The other system of thought is the Reflective System. This system is deliberate and self-conscious. It is the one at work when people decide which college to attend, where to go on trips, and (under most circumstances) whether or not to get married.[9]

Fallacies and biases

Because of these differences and conflicts between these systems, people are often subject to making mistakes that are the result of widely occurring biases, heuristics, and fallacies.

These include:

  • Anchoring: a cognitive bias wherein one relies too heavily on one trait or piece of information. An example would be a resident of Chicago who is asked to guess the population of Milwaukee. Knowing that Milwaukee is a major city, but certainly not as large as Chicago, the person would take the population of Chicago (roughly 3 million) and divide it by, say, three (arriving at one million). A resident of Green Bay (which has a population of around 100,000) might know that Milwaukee is larger than Green Bay, and triple the population of their home city to arrive at a guess (of 300,000). The difference in guesses of people because of their geographical location is an instance of anchoring. The real population of Milwaukee is about 580,000.
  • Availability heuristic: when people predict the frequency of an event based on how easily an example can be brought to mind. The authors state that this could help explain why people think that homicides occur more than suicides, as examples of homicides are more readily available. The availability heuristic can have negative effects in business and politics, because people will overstate risks, resulting in people purchasing unnecessary insurance, or governments pursuing social goals at the expense of other more fruitful ones.[10]
  • Representativeness heuristic: where people judge the probability or frequency of a hypothesis by considering how much the hypothesis resembles available data. An example would be perceiving meaningful patterns in information that is in fact random. These include false accounts of "cancer clusters" and the common belief in basketball that players can get "hot". Due to the number of shots taken, players are bound to have times when they score many shots in a row, but basketball fans wrongly believe that a player that has just made a series of shots is more likely to make their next shot.[11]
  • Status quo bias: this is when people are very likely to continue a course of action since it has been traditionally the one pursued, even though this course of action may clearly not be in their best interest. An example of the status-quo bias at work would be when magazine companies offer trials of their magazines for free, but then, after the trial has ended, continue to send magazines and charge the customer until he or she actively ends the subscription. This leads to many people receiving and paying for magazines they do not read.[12]
  • Herd mentality: people are heavily influenced by the actions of others. Sunstein and Thaler cite a famous study by Solomon Asch where people, due to peer pressure, answer certain questions in a way that was clearly false (such as saying that two lines are the same length, when they clearly are not).

Because human beings are subject to these various errors and flawed thinking patterns, Sunstein and Thaler endorse libertarian paternalism.

Libertarian paternalism

Libertarian paternalism is the union of two political notions that are commonly viewed as being at odds: libertarianism and paternalism.

Sunstein and Thaler state that "the libertarian aspect of our strategies lies in the straightforward insistence that, in general, people should be free to do what they like-and to opt out of undesirable arrangements if they want to do so".[13] The paternalistic portion of the term "lies in the claim that it is legitimate for choice architects to try to influence people's behavior in order to make their lives longer, healthier, and better".[14]

Choice architecture describes the way in which decisions are influenced by how the choices are presented. It is in arranging the choice architecture in a certain way that individuals can be nudged in a certain way without taking away their freedom of choice. A simple example of a nudge would be placing healthy foods in a school cafeteria at eye level, while putting less healthy junk food in harder to reach places. Individuals are not prevented from eating whatever they want, but the arranging of the food choices in that way has the effect of decreasing consumption of junk food and increasing consumption of healthier foods.[15]

Policy recommendations

Sunstein and Thaler use their notions of nudges within the context of choice architecture to propose policy recommendations that they believe are in the spirit of libertarian paternalism. They have recommendations in the areas of finance, health, the environment, schools, and marriage.[16] They believe these problems can at least be partially addressed by improving the choice architecture.

Retirement saving

Thaler and Sunstein point out that many Americans are not saving enough for retirement. They state that "in 2005 the personal savings rate for Americans was negative for the first time since 1932 and 1933-the Great Depression years".

One change they offer is creating better default plans for employees. Employees would be able to adopt any plan they like, but, if no action is taken, they would automatically be enrolled in an expertly designed program. They also propose what they refer to as the "Save More Tomorrow" plan. This is to address the issue of people having the desire to save more, yet procrastinating on actually doing so. This program would invite "participants to commit themselves, in advance, to a series of contribution increases timed to coincide with pay raises".[17]

Health care

The book contains an analysis of the Bush administration program Medicare Part D. Thaler and Sunstein state that "on some dimensions Bush was on the right track" with the plan, but that, "as a piece of choice architecture...it suffered from a cumbersome design that impeded good decision making".[18] Specifically, they think that default choices for programs should not have been random, and that beneficiaries of the program were not given adequate resources to deal with the number of choices they were faced with. They think that seniors who did not sign up for a program should have one assigned to them, and that, yearly, they should be mailed an itemized list of all drugs they had used and all of the fees they incurred. This information would be freely available online, where beneficiaries could easily compare their programs with other similar ones.[19]

Sunstein and Thaler also propose a way to increase organ donation rates in the United States. They argue that a mandated choice program should be put in place, where, in order for someone to renew their drivers license, they must say whether or not they would like to be an organ donor. They also advocate the creation of websites which would suggest that the wide community supports organ donation in order to nudge people into becoming organ donors themselves.[20]

Reception

George Will, in a review for Newsweek magazine, stated that "nudges have the additional virtue of annoying those busybody, nanny-state liberals who, as the saying goes, do not care what people do as long as it is compulsory".[21]

British journalist Bryan Appleyard, in a review for The Times, was critical of the book, describing it as a "very, very dull read, a dogged march through social policies with boring lists of what nudges should be imposed and how" and that "what the book needs is not more examples but more elaboration of the central idea".[22]

Christopher Shea, for The Washington Post wrote that "In the end, it must be said, the profusion of proposals in Nudge, however worthy, and the countless summaries of studies supporting them grow a bit wearisome. As influential as the book is likely to be, it's hard to imagine it pushing its way alongside Malcolm Gladwell's Blink (inferior social science, far breezier style) on the bestseller list".[23]

Elizabeth Kolbert writing for The New Yorker held reservations about some of the book's conclusions when she wrote that

"many of the suggestions in “Nudge” seem like good ideas, and even, as with “Save More Tomorrow,” practical ones. The whole project, though, as Thaler and Sunstein acknowledge, raises some pretty awkward questions. If the “nudgee” can’t be depended on to recognize his own best interests, why stop at a nudge? Why not offer a “push,” or perhaps even a “shove”? And if people can’t be trusted to make the right choices for themselves how can they possibly be trusted to make the right decisions for the rest of us?"[24]

In July 2011, a subgroup of the UK House of Lords Science and Technology Committee concluded a year-long review of behavioral change based on 148 written submissions and evidence from 70 witnesses. The review was led by Baroness Neuberger. In an interview with The Guardian newspaper[25] Baroness Neuberger reports finding “precious little” evidence for effective impact of “Nudge”:

"Ýou need more than just nudge ... Behavioural change interventions appear to work best when they're part of a package of regulation and fiscal measures ... all politicians love quick fixes ... one of the problems with all of this is if you really want to change people's behaviour it takes a very long time … you have to look at a 20- to 25-year span before you get a full change of behaviour."

Notes

  1. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 3-7.
  2. ^ "Lured Toward the Right Choice" - Time.com Retrieved December 6, 2009
  3. ^ "Nudge The Gentle Power of Choice Architecture" - Capital Ideas Retrieved December 6, 2009
  4. ^ "Why a nudge from the state beats a slap" - The Observer Retrieved December 6, 2009
  5. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 6.
  6. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 7.
  7. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 19.
  8. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 19.
  9. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 20.
  10. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 25-26.
  11. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 30.
  12. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 35.
  13. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 5.
  14. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 5.
  15. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 1.
  16. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 105.
  17. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 115.
  18. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 162.
  19. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 175.
  20. ^ Sunstein and Thaler, p. 182-83.
  21. ^ "Nudge Against the Fudge" - Newsweek.com Retrieved December 6, 2009
  22. ^ "Nudge: The Sunday Times review by Bryan Appleyard" - Times Online Retrieved December 6, 2009
  23. ^ "Who's in Control Here?" - The Washington Post Retrieved December 6, 2009
  24. ^ "WHAT WAS I THINKING?" The New Yorker Retrieved December 6, 2009
  25. ^ "Julia Neuberger: 'A nudge in the right direction won't run the big society'" The Guardian Retrieved July 17, 2011

References

  • Sunstein, Cass; Thaler, Richard (2008). Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness. Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0-14-311526-7. 

External links


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно решить контрольную?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Nudge — may refer to: The police Nudge (instant messaging), an attention getting feature in instant messaging software The Nudge , a nickname for rock star Ted Nugent Nudge (book), a book on choice architecture by Richard Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein… …   Wikipedia

  • Nudge Nudge — Candid Photography , better known as Nudge Nudge , is a sketch from the third Monty Python s Flying Circus episode, How to Recognise Different Types of Trees From Quite a Long Way Away featuring Eric Idle (author of the sketch) and Terry Jones as …   Wikipedia

  • nudge theory — /ˈnʌdʒ θɪəri/ (say nuj thearree) noun (plural nudge theories) a theory of how to effect beneficial social change by offering positive reinforcement and suggestions rather than explicit instructions, legal enforcement, etc. {from the book Nudge… …  

  • Monty Python's Big Red Book — Cover of Monty Python s Big Red Book Monty Python s Big Red Book is a humour book comprising mostly material derived and reworked from the first few years of the Monty Python s Flying Circus BBC television series. It was first published in 1971… …   Wikipedia

  • List of characters in Maximum Ride — This is a list of all the characters in Maximum Ride . The FlockMaximum Ride (Max)Maximum Ride (Max) is fourteen years old, the oldest of the avian human hybrids and the leader of the Flock. She is 5 8 and has a wingspan of about 13 feet across.… …   Wikipedia

  • Maximum Ride — Maximum Ride: The Angel Experiment Maximum Ride: School s Out Forever Maximum Ride: Saving the World and Other Extreme Sports Maximum Ride: The Final Warning MAX: A Maximum Ride Novel Fang: A Maximum Ride Novel Angel: A Maximum Ride Novel… …   Wikipedia

  • Evolutionary history of life — Although evidence of early life is scarce and often difficult to interpret, it appears that life appeared on Earth relatively soon (on the geologic time scale) after the planet had cooled enough for liquid water to be present. The dominant theory …   Wikipedia

  • List of Maximum Ride characters — This is a list of characters in the Maximum Ride children s book series by James Patterson. Contents 1 The Flock 1.1 Fang 1.2 Iggy 1.3 Nudge …   Wikipedia

  • Monty Python — The Python troupe in 1969 Back row: Graham Chapman, Eric Idle, Terry Gilliam Front row: Terry Jones, John Cleese, Michael Palin …   Wikipedia

  • List of Monty Python's Flying Circus episodes — This is a list of all 45 episodes from the television series Monty Python s Flying Circus: Series Episodes Originally aired First in the series Last in the series 1 13 5 October 1969 11 January 1970 2 13 15 September 1970 22 Dece …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”