Byzantine economy

Byzantine economy

The Byzantine economy was among the most advanced in Europe and the Mediterranean for many centuries. Constantinople was a prime hub in a trading network that at various times extended across nearly all of Eurasia and North Africa. Some scholars argue that, up until the arrival of the Arabs in the 7th century, the Empire had the most powerful economy in the world. The Arab conquests, however, would represent a substantial reversal of fortunes contributing to a period of decline and stagnation. Constantine V's reforms (c. 765) marked the beginning of a revival that continued until 1204. From the 10th century until the end of the 12th, the Byzantine Empire projected an image of luxury, and the travelers were impressed by the wealth accumulated in the capital. All this changed with the arrival of the Fourth Crusade, which was an economic catastrophe. The Palaiologoi tried to revive the economy, but the late Byzantine state would not gain full control of either the foreign or domestic economic forces.

One of the economic foundations of the empire was trade. The state strictly controlled both the internal and the international trade, and retained the monopoly of issuing coinage. Constantinople remained the single most important commercial centre of Europe for much of the Medieval era, which status it held until the Republic of Venice slowly began to overtake Byzantine merchants in trade; first through tax exemption under the Komnenoi, then under the Latin Empire.

Economic and fiscal history

The Byzantine economy suffered less from the Barbarian raids that plagued the Western Roman Empire. Under Diocletian's reign, the Eastern Roman Empire's annual revenue was at 9,400,000 "solidi", out of a total of 18,000,000 "solidi" for the entire Roman Empire.W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 144] These estimates can be compared to the AD 150 annual revenue of 14,500,000 "solidi" and the AD 215 of 22,000,000 "solidi". By the end of Marcian's reign, the annual revenue for the Eastern empire was 7,800,000 "solidi", thus allowing him to amass about 100,000 pounds of gold or 7,200,000 "solidi" for the imperial treasury.W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 144] The wealth of Constantinople can be seen by how Justin I used formatnum:3700 pounds of gold just for celebrating his own consulship. By the end of his reign, Anastasius I had managed to collect for the treasury an amount of 23,000,000 "solidi" or 320,000 pounds of gold. At the start of Justinian I's reign, the Emperor had inherited a surplus formatnum:28800000 "solidi" (formatnum:400000 pounds of gold) from Anastasius I and Justin I.Harl, [http://www.tulane.edu/~august/H303/handouts/Finances.htm Finances under Justinian] .] It has been estimated that before Justinian I's reconquests the state had an annual revenue of formatnum:5000000 "solidi"; after his reconquests in 550, the annual revenue was increased to formatnum:6000000 "solidi". Even though his revenues were increased, Justinian I had little money left towards the end of his reign partly because of the Justinian Plague, and the Roman-Persian Wars (Justinian spent large amounts of money in annual subsidies to the Sassanian Empire.Norwich, "Byzantium: The Early Centuries", 195, 229,260] ), which both harmed the economy. In addition to these expenses, the rebuilding of Hagia Sophia cost formatnum:20000 pounds of gold.Heather, "The Fall of the Roman Empire", 283] At the beginning of his reign, Justin II was forced to pay 80,000 silver coins to the Avars for peace and later his wife Sophia paid 45,000 "solidi" to Khosrau I in return for a year's truce,Norwich, "Byzantium: The Early Centuries", 269] and then Tiberius II Constantine also gave away formatnum:7200 pounds of gold each year for four years. Since Emperor Heraclius changed the empire's official language from Latin to Greek in around AD 620, the "solidus" (plural: "solidi") would thereafter be known by its Greek name, the "nomisma" (plural: "nomismata").K. Harl, [http://www.tulane.edu/~august/H303/currency/Isaurian.htm] ]

The Byzantine-Arab Wars reduced the territory of the Empire to a third in the 7th century and the economy slumped; in 780 the Byzantine Empire's revenues were reduced to only formatnum:1800000 "nomismata". From the 8th century onward the Empire's economy improved dramatically. This was a blessing for Byzantium in more than one way; the economy, the administration of gold coinage and the farming of the Anatolian peninsula served to meet the military's constant demands. Since Byzantium was in a constant state of warfare with her neighbours (even if only by raiding) the military required weapons to be manufactured by the bigger cities (such as Thessaloniki) whilst the smaller towns were subject to grain, wine and even biscuit requisitions by Imperial officers. Even though the soldiers' pay was minimal large armies were a considerable strain on Byzantium. As gold coins were spent on soldiers to serve in the army, these would in time spend their money acquiring their own goods and much revenue would return to the state in the form of taxation. As a result, the Byzantine economy was self-sufficient, allowing it to thrive in the Dark Ages. The success of the Byzantine army was in no small part due to the success of her economy.

Around 775, the land and head taxes yielded an estimated 1,600,000 "nomismata" annually for the empire. Commerce during this period slumped, therefore only contributing 200,000 "nomismata" annually. The expenditures of the period were quite large when compared to the annual revenues. Approximately 600,000 "nomismata" went to the payroll of the army annually while other military costs took another 600,000 "nomismata" annually. Supporting the Byzantine bureaucracy needed 400,000 "nomismata". Also, imperial largess cost the treasury 100,000 "nomismata" every year. All of these expenses meant that the Byzantine government had only about 100,000 "nomismata" in surplus revenue each year for treaties, bribes, or gifts. [Harl, [http://www.tulane.edu/~august/H303/handouts/c850.htm] ]

Expenses again soared, when a massive Muslim army invaded the empire in 806, forcing Nikephoros I to pay a ransom of formatnum:50000 gold coins and a yearly tribute of formatnum:30000 gold coins.Norwich, "Byzantium: The Early Centuries", 6] In order to impress the Caliph of Baghdad, Theophilos distributed 36,000 gold coins to the citizens of Baghdad, and in 838, he was forced to pay formatnum:100000 gold dinars to the Caliph. The Byzantine economic recovery in the early 800s can be seen by the fact that Emperor Theophilios was able to leave 7,000,000 "nomismata" in the imperial treasury for his successor in AD 842.W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 445] After Theophilos' death his wife Theodora II continued his successful policies and even increased the imperial reserves to 7,848,000 "nomismata", but unfortunately under their son Michael III the reserves dwindled to about 100,000 "nomismata".W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 450] However, under Basil I's prudent economic policies, the state quickly raised 4,300,000 "nomismata", far more even than the empire's annual revenue of formatnum:3300000 "nomismata". Sviatoslav I was paid formatnum:15000 pounds of gold by Nikephoros II to invade Bulgaria in AD 968. By the time of Basil II's death in 1025, the annual income had increased to formatnum:5900000 "nomismata", which allowed him to amass a large surplus of 14,400,000 "nomismata" (200,000 pounds of gold) in the treasury for his successor.W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 577]

Around 850, the land and head taxes yielded an estimated 2,900,000 "nomismata" annually for the empire. Commerce during this period increased dramatically, therefore contributing 400,000 "nomismata" annually. The expenditures of the period were large, but manageable by the treasury. Approximately 1,400,000 "nomismata" went to the payroll of the army annually while other military costs took another 800,000 "nomismata" annually. Supporting the Byzantine bureaucracy needed 500,000 "nomismata". Also, imperial largess cost the treasury 100,000 "nomismata" every year. All of these expenses meant that the Byzantine government had about 500,000 "nomismata" in surplus revenue each year, much more than in the 8th century. [Harl, [http://www.tulane.edu/~august/H303/handouts/c850.htm] ]

From the tenth century, however, until the end of the twelfth, the Byzantine Empire projected an image of wealth and luxury. Constantine V's reforms (c. 765) marked the beginning of a revival that continued until 1204.Magdalino, "Medieval Constantinople", 3] The travelers who visited its capital were impressed by the wealth accumulated in Constantinople; riches that also served the state's diplomatic purposes as a means of propaganda, and a way to impress foreigners as well its own citizens. When Liutprand of Cremona was sent as an ambassador to the Byzantine capital in the 940s, he was overwhelmed by the imperial residence, the luxurious meals, and acrobatic entertainment.Laiou, "Writing the Economic History of Byzantium", 3
* Neumann, "Sublime Diplomacy", 870-871] Nevertheless, the Byzantine economy went into a long decline until the Comnenian Dynasty was able to revive the economy. In the aftermath of the Battle of Manzikert, Alp Arslan at first suggested to Emperor Romanos IV a ransom of formatnum:10000000 gold coins, but later reduced it to formatnum:1500000 gold coins with a further formatnum:360000 gold coins annually.Norwich, "A Short History of Byzantium", 241]

In exchange for an alliance, Alexios I sent formatnum:360000 gold coins to Emperor Henry IV.Norwich, "Byzantium: The Decline and Fall", 21] The wealth of the empire under the Comnenians can be seen by how Emperor Manuel I was able to ransom some Latin prisoners from the Muslims for formatnum:100000 dinars, then formatnum:150000 dinars for Bohemond III in AD 1165, formatnum:120000 dinars for Raynald of Chatillon, and formatnum:150000 dinars for Baldwin of Ibelin in 1180.Harris, "Byzantium and The Crusades", 43] When Manuel became emperor he ordered 2 gold coins to be given to every householder in Constantinople and 200 pounds of gold (including 200 silver coins annually) to be given to the Byzantine Church.Norwich, "Byzantium: The Decline and Fall", 88] When his niece Theodora married King Baldwin III of Jerusalem in 1157, Manuel gave her a dowry of formatnum:100000 gold coins, formatnum:10000 gold coins for marriage expenses, and presents (jewels and silk garments) which were worth formatnum:14000 gold coins total.Harris, "Byzantium and The Crusades", 108] The expense of Manuel's involvement in Italy must have cost the treasury a great deal (probably more than 2,160,000 "hyperpyra" or formatnum:30000 pounds of gold).W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 643] Then he also promised to pay formatnum:5000 pounds of gold to the Pope and the Curia. During his reign, Manuel bought a very rich jewel (for formatnum:62000 silver marks) which was used during the coronation Latin Emperor Baldwin I.T. Madden, "Crusades: The Illustrated History", 114] The main source of the state's wealth in the twelfth century was the "kommerkion", a customs duty levied at Constantinople on all imports and exports, which was stated to have collected formatnum:20000 "hyperpyra" each day.Harris, "Byzantium and The Crusades", 25-26] This, combined with other sources of income, meant the empire's annual revenue was at 5,600,000 "hyperpyra" in 1150.W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 705] Under the Komnenian emperors, many exemptions of trade duties were given to the Italian traders, which meant the loss of about 50,000 "hyperpyra" annually.W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 705] A Venetian embassy visited Constantinople in 1184 and an agreement was reached that compensation of 1,500 pounds of gold (or 108,000 "hyperpyra") would be paid for the losses incurred in 1171.J. Phillips, "The Fourth Crusade and the Sack of Constantinople", 133]

After the demise of the Komnenoi, the Byzantine economy declined under the impact of several factors: the dismemberment of the Empire after 1204, the successive territorial losses to the Turks (although the strong economic interaction of Byzantine territories with those lost by the Empire continued), and the Italian expansion in the Mediterranean and the Black Sea.Jakoby, "The Economy of Late Byzantium", 81] When Isaac II Angelos became Emperor in 1185, a mob broke into the palace and carried off formatnum:1200 pounds of gold and formatnum:3000 pounds of silver.Norwich, "Byzantium: The Decline and Fall", 153] In 1195, Holy Roman Emperor Henry VI forced Byzantine Emperor Alexios III Angelos to pay him a tribute of formatnum:1000 pounds of gold (originally formatnum:5000 pounds of gold) and in 1204 Alexios III took formatnum:1000 pounds of gold (or 72,000 "hyperpyra") when he fled Constantinople.Harris, "Byzantium and The Crusades", 148-149; Norwich, "Byzantium: The Decline and Fall", 163] The presence of the crusading army not only culminated in a violent sack that dispersed and destroyed the accumulated wealth, and culture of centuries, but was accompanied by a series of fires that ravaged the northern and central sections of the city resulting in a steady exodus of the city's residents to the Greek centers of government in exile. The sack of Constantinople by Latin crusaders in 1204 was an economic catastrophe. Due to the financial crisis, the state could only pay formatnum:100000 silver marks (formatnum:65000 pounds of pure silver) out of formatnum:200000 silver marks (equivalent to 800,000 "hyperpyra") to the Crusaders in 1204.W. Treadgold, "A History of Byzantine State and Society", 663] The official tally of plunder from Constantinople was about formatnum:900000 silver marks, the equivalent of about 3,600,000 "hyperpyra" or 50,000 pounds of gold.Konstam, "Historical Atlas of The Crusades", 162] W. Treadgold, "A History of Byzantine State and Society", 663] The impoverished Latin emperors melted down statues for coin, while the Venetians exported their declining profits, along with choice relics and architecture spolia for their churches. In 1237, Latin Emperor Baldwin II pawned the Crown of Thorns to a Venetian merchant for formatnum:13134 gold coins.Harris, "Byzantium and The Crusades", 170]

By the time the Palaiologoi took power, Italian merchants had come to dominate the trade by sea whilst Turkic incursions prevented any success from trade across roads. Michael VIII Palaiologos strove to restore the capital's greatness, but the resources of the empire were inadequate. In 1282, Michael VIII was forced to drain the treasury to pay the enormous bribe of formatnum:60000 "hyperpyra" to King Peter III of Aragon to invade the Kingdom of Sicily.Harris, "Byzantium and The Crusades", 180] Constantinople became once more, as in the seventh and eighth centuries, a ruralized network of scattered nuclei; in the final decades before the fall, the population numbered formatnum:70000 people. [Magdalino, "Medieval Constantinople", 535-536] Gradually, the state also lost its influence on the modalities of trade and the price mechanisms, and its control over the outflow of precious metals and, according to some scholars, even over the minting of coins.Matschke, "Commerce, Trade, Markets, and Money", 805-806] By 1303, the empire's annual revenue dropped to less than 1,800,000 "hyperpyra", under Andronikos II Palaiologos. In 1321, only with extreme effort was Andonikos II able to raise revenues to 1,000,000 "hyperpyra".W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 750]

The Byzantine economy had declined so much that by 1343, Empress Anne of Savoy had to pawn the Byzantine crown jewels for formatnum:30000 Venetian ducats, which was the equivalent of 60,000 "hyperpyra".W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 768] In 1348, Constantinople had an annual revenue of formatnum:30000 "hyperpyra" while across the Golden Horn in the Genoese colony of Galata, the annual revenue was formatnum:200000 "hyperpyra". When Emperor John VI Kantakouzenos attempted to rebuild the Byzantine navy, he was only able to raise an inadequate formatnum:50000 "hyperpyra". In 1453, the economy of the Genoan quarter in Constantinople had a revenue 7 times greater than that of the whole Empire - not even a shadow of its former self. The only success during this period was when the Republic of Genoa agreed to pay a war indemnity of formatnum:100000 "hyperpyra" in 1349. When Emperor John V Palaiologos was captured by Ivan Alexander in AD 1366, he was forced to pay a ransom of formatnum:180000 florins. In AD 1370, the empire owed Venice, formatnum:25663 "hyperpyra" (of which only formatnum:4500 "hyperpyra" had so far been paid) for damage done to Venetian property.Norwich, "Byzantium: The Decline and Fall", 334] In February of 1424, Manuel II Palaiologos signed an unfavorable peace treaty with the Ottoman Turks, whereby the Byzantine Empire was forced to pay formatnum:300000 silver coins to the Sultan on annual basis. Emperor Constantine XI owed Venice 17,163 "hyperpyra" when he died in AD 1453.Nicolle, "Constantinople 1453: The End of Byzantium", 84]

The exact amount of annual income the Byzantine government received, is a matter of considerable debate, due to the scantness and ambiguous nature of the primary sources. The following table contains approximate estimates.Simple timeline
event-title=Annual Revenue
type=style=""
305|9,400,000 "solidi"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 144]
457|7,800,000 "solidi"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 144]
518|8,500,000 "solidi"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 276]
540|11,300,000 "solidi"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 277]
565|8,500,000 "solidi"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 278]
641|3,700,000 "nomismata"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 411]
668|2,000,000 "nomismata"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 413]
775|2,000,000 "nomismata"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 413]
842|3,100,000 "nomismata"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 575]
959|4,000,000 "nomismata"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 575]
1025|6,000,000 "nomismata"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 575]
1150|5,600,000 "hyperpyra"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 705]
1300|1,800,000 "hyperpyra"
1321|1,000,000 "hyperpyra"W. Treadgold, "A History of the Byzantine State and Society", 841]

tate's role

The state retained the monopoly of issuing coinage, and had the power to intervene in other important sectors of the economy. It exercised formal control over interest rates, and set the parameters for the activity of the guilds and corporations in Constantinople, in which the state has a special interest (e.g the sale of silk) or whose members exercised a profession that was of importance for trade. The emperor and his officials intervened at times of crisis to ensure the provisioning of the capital and to keep down the price of cereals. For this reason, the empire strictly controlled both the internal circulation of commodities, and the international trade (certainly in intent; to a considerable degree also in practice).Laiou, "Writing the Economic History of Byzantium, 3; Zakythinos, "The Character of the Economy", 255-256] Additionally, the state often collected part of the surplus in the form of tax, and put it back into circulation, through redistribution in the form of salaries to state officials of the army, or in the form of investment in public works, buildings, or works of art. [Laiou, "Writing the Economic History of Byzantium", 255-256]

Coinage

Coinage was the basic form of money in Byzantium, although credit existed: archival documents indicate that both banking and bankers were not as primitive as has sometimes been implied.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 909] The Byzantine Empire was capable of making a durable monetary system function for more that a thousand years, from Constantine I to 1453, because of its relative flexibility. Money was both product and instrument of a complex and developed financial and fiscal organization that contributed to the economic integration of its territory. [Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 910]

The first features of the administrative organization of monetary production were first established by Diocletian and Constantine, and were still in existence at the beginning of the seventh century.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 911] During Byzantine history, supervision of the mintsUnder Anastasius I there were only four mints in the empire, but Justinian's reconquests resulted in a significant increase in their number. As a result of an administrative reorganization and of the loss of much of the empire's territories, their number was again greatly reduced during the seventh century.(Grierson, "Byzantine Coinage", 5)] belonged to the Emperor; thus the government controlled, to a certain degree, the money supply. Nevertheless, the Emperor and his government were not always capable of conducting a monetary policy in the modern meaning of the term.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 917]

Ever since the creation of the Byzantine monetary system by Constantine in 312, its pivot had been golden "solidus", a coinage whose nominal value was equal to its intrinsic value, as is proven by the Theodosian Code. [Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 918] "Solidus" became a highly priced and stable means of storing and transferring valuesEsler, "The Early Christian World", 1081] Novel 16 of Valentinian III punished with death anyone who dared "refuse or reduce a gold "solidus" of good weight." [Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 918-919] Weight and fineness of the coinage were joined by another element: the authenticity of the stamp, which served to guarantee the other two.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 919] Alongside this "real"-value gold coinage, and a slightly overvalued silver coinage, there was also a bronze coinage of a fiduciary nature that made up the second specific feature of the monetary system. At the end of the tenth and in the eleventh centuries, money underwent a profound transformation, followed by a crisis; the denomination affected all metals at different dates, and according to different modalities.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 930] The reform of Alexios I Komnenos put an end to this crisis by restoring a gold coinage of high fineness, the "hyperpyron", and by creating a new system destined to endure for about two centuries.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 932] In 1304 the introduction of the "basilikon", a pure silver coinage modeled on the Venetian ducat marked the abandonment of Komnenian structures under the influence of western models. The system that began in 1367 was constructed around the "stavraton", a heavy silver, equivalent to twice the weight of fine metal of the last "hyperpyra".Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 933-934] By the end of the twelfth century, especially from 1204 on, the political fragmentation of the empire resulted in the creation of coinages that were either "national" (e.g. in Trebizond in 1222, in Bulgaria in 1218, and in Serbia in 1228), colonial or feudal. Venetian coins soon penetrated the monetary circulation in Byzantium.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 961] This situation stand in contrast with the monopoly that Byzantine currency had enjoyed until the twelfth century, within its own frontiers, and through its dissusion in the lands beyond - a measure of its political and economic influence.Morrisson, "Byzantine Money", 962]

Trade

One of the economic foundations of the empire was trade. Constantinople was located on important east-west and north-south trade routes. Trebizond was an important port in the eastern trade. The exact routes varied over the years with wars and the political situation. Imports and exports were uniformly taxed at ten percent.

Grain and silk were two of the most important commodities for the empire. The Arab conquest of Egypt and Syria harmed the Byzantium's trade, and affected the provisioning of the capital with grain. As the population increased in the ninth and tenth centuries, the demand for grain also increased. There was a functioning market for grain in Constantinople, but it was not entirely self-regulating: the state could play a role in the availability of grain, and the formation of prices.Laiou, "Exchange and Trade", 720]

Silk was used by the state both as a means of payment, and of diplomacy. Raw silk was bought from China and India and made up into fine brocades and cloth-of-gold that commanded high prices through the world. Later, silk worms were smuggled into the empire and the overland silk trade became less important. After Justinian I the manufacturing and sale of silk had become an imperial monopoly, only processed in imperial factories, and sold to authorized buyers.Laiou, "Exchange and Trade", 703] The raw silk merchants could buy the raw silk from outside Constantinople but did not themselves have the authority to travel outside the city to get it - possibly in order not to jeopardize the activities of the provincial merchants selling the silk.Laiou, "Exchange and Trade", 718]

The other commodities that were traded, in Constantinople and elsewhere, were numerous: oil, wine, salt fish, meat, vegetables, other alimentary products, salt, timber and wax. Ceramics, linen, and wooden cloth were also items of trade. Luxury items, such as silks, perfumes and spices were also important. Trade in slaves is attested, both on behalf of the state, and, possibly, by private individuals. International trade was practiced not only in Constantinople, which was until the late twelfth century an important center of the eastern luxury trade, but also in other cities that functioned as centers of inter-regional and international trade, such as Thessaloniki and Trebizond.Laiou, "Exchange and Trade", 723] Textiles must have been by far the most important item of export; silks were certainly imported into Egypt, and they also appear also in Bulgaria and the West.Laiou, "Exchange and Trade", 725] The empire had also trading activity through Venice (as long as the latter was part of the empire): salt, wood, iron, and slaves, as well luxury products from the East, were the products exchanged. In 992, Basil II concluded a treaty with Pietro Orseolo II by the terms that Venice's custom duties in Constantinople would be reduced from 30 "nomismata" to 17 "nomismata" in return for the Venetians agreeing to transport Byzantine troops to Southern Italy in times of war.Laiou, "Exchange and Trade", 726; Norwich, "A History of Venice", 158] During the eleventh and twelfth centuries Italian trade in the empire took place under privileged conditions, incorporated in treaties and privileges that were granted to Amalfi, Venice, Genoa, and Pisa.Laiou, "Exchange and Trade", 746]

The Fourth Crusade and the Venetian domination of trade in the area created new conditions. In 1261, the Genoese were given generous customs privileges, and six years later the Venetians regained their original quarter in Constantinople.Matschke, "Commerce, Trade, Markets, and Money", 771] The two northern Italian trading powers created the conditions that allowed them to reach any point in Byzantium, and to put the entire economic region in the service of their commercial interests. [Matschke, "Commerce, Trade, Markets, and Money", 772]

The Palaiologoi tried to revive the economy, and re-establish traditional forms of political supervision, and guidance of the economy. It was, however, apparent that the late Byzantine state was unable to gain full control of either the foreign or domestic economic forces. Gradually, the state lost its influence on the modalities of trade and the price mechanisms, and its control over the outflow of precious metals and, according to some scholars, even over the minting of coins. Late Byzantine officials supposed to implement a regulatory policy used the state prerogatives placed into their hands to pursue their private businesses. Private commercial activity was also affected by the crises in foreign policy, and the internal erosion of Byzantium.Matschke, "Commerce, Trade, Markets, and Money", 805-806]

Agriculture

Development in the rural economy, though certainly slow, was continuous from the eight to the beginning of the fourteenth century.Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 232] Areas close to the sea featuring cereal crops, vines, and olive groves (the interior of the Balkans, and Asia Minor concentrated on stock raising) were relatively well-favored, and appear to have played an important role in the development of the Byzantine economy. The peasantry's tools changed little through the ages, and remained rudimentary, which resulted in a low ratio of productivity to labor. Nevertheless, according to certain scholars, the permanence of techniques, and tools are evidence of their successful adaptation to the environment. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 234-235]

From the seventh to the twelfth century the social organization of production was arranged round two poles: estate and village (a collection of free smallholders). The village social structure was the organizational form best adapted to insecure conditions, with the estate fulfilling this role once conditions were safe again. There was in principle a clear distinction between tenants who lived on the estates (and owed dues to the master of the place), and the village inhabitants, many of whom owned land, and consequently paid taxes to the state. Nevertheless, not all the cultivators on the estate lived there, and not all enjoyed a special status. Some of them, whether slaves or wage laborers; references to wage laborers occur continuously from the seventh century to the end of the Byzantine period. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 242] In the same way, the inhabitants of a village would not all be landholders, and of these, not all would be farmers; some village proprietors held the lowest rank of aristocrat status, and were wealthier that tenant farmers. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 236-237] The distinction between landholder and tenant farmer ("paroikos") was weakened once tenures held by "paroikoi" were considered hereditary, and once some "paroikoi" achieved owner status. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 238] From the tenth century on, large estates assumed the leading role that had been held until then by villages, albeit in an economy that was henceforth orientated toward demand, with monetary exchanges taking a larger share. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 284] By the beginning of the fourteenth century, the Macedonian countryside was made up of an almost unbroken network of estates that had replaced the former network of communes. Villages that are known to have possessed commune status in the tenth century became estates of the fisc, after which they might be ceded to a monastery or lay person. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 289]

The population was dense in the sixth century, but it diminished in the seventh, and eight centuries. Epidemics (such as the plague of 541/542 and its recurrences until 747) seem to have had greater effects on population volume than wars. From the ninth century on the population of the empire increased, but it was unevenly distributed. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 267-268] A growing population would imply an increase in the area under cultivation. The automatic effect of a larger population was also amplified by the demand from a growing number of people who did not produce much or at all. Indeed, it is estimated that areas under cultivation must have almost doubled, and that the extension of crops might have affected a shift in the location of grazing lands, and pushed back the woodlands. [Lefort, "The Rural Economy", 270]

After the Battle of Manzikert in 1071, most of the interior of Anatolia was lost to the Turks, and the remaining territories of the Empire were dominated by the cities the Byzantines were able to hold on to.

The conquest of the empire by the Crusades in 1204, and the subsequent division of the Byzantine territories affected the agrarian economy as it did other aspects of economic organization, and economic life. These territories split among small Greek and Latin states, lost much of the cohesion they may have had: the Byzantine state could not function as a unifying force, and, in the thirteenth century, there was very little to replace it.Laiou, "The Agrarian Economy", 311] The thirteenth century is the last period, during which one may speak of significant land clearance, that is, the act of bringing previously uncultivated land into cultivation. But the progressive impoverishment of the peasantry, entailed the decline of a certain aggregate demand, and resulted in a concentration of resources in the hands of large landowners, who must have had considerable surpluses.Laiou, "The Agrarian Economy", 369]

The demographic expansion came to an end in the course of the fourteenth century, during which a deterioration of the status of "paroikoi", an erosion of the economic function of village by the role of the large estates, and a precipitous demographic decline in Macedonia is established by modern research. [Laiou, "The Agrarian Economy", 314-315, 317] The upper levels of the aristocracy lost their fortunes, and eventually there was a concentration of property on the hands of the larger, and more privileged monasteries, at least in Macedonia. The monasteries did not show great versatility or innovative spirit, and the rural economy had to wait, for its recovery, until the effects of epidemics had been reversed, security had been established, and communications restored: that is, until the firm establishment of the Ottomans in the Balkans.

Citations and notes

References


*cite book|last=Esler|first=Philip Francis|title=The Early Christian World|year=2000|publisher=Routledge|isbn=0-415-33312-1|chapter=Constantine and the Empire|
*cite book |last=Grierson|first=Philip|title=Byzantine Coinage|year=1999|publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|url=http://www.doaks.org/byzcoins.pdf|isbn=0-88402-274-9
*cite web |last=Harl|first=Kenneth W|url= http://www.tulane.edu/~august/H303/currency/Isaurian.htm|title=Currency in the Isaurian, Amorian and Macedonian Ages (717-1092) |accessdate=2008-03-19 |date= |work=Early Medieval and Byzantine Civilization: Constantine to Crusades |publisher=Tulane University
*cite web |last=Harl|first=Kenneth W|url= http://www.tulane.edu/~august/H303/handouts/Finances.htm|title=Finances under Justinian |accessdate=2008-03-19 |date= |work=Early Medieval and Byzantine Civilization: Constantine to Crusades |publisher=Tulane University
*cite book|last=Harris|first=Jonathan|title=Byzantium and the Crusades|publisher=Hambledon and London|year=2003|isbn=1-85285-298-4
*cite book|last=Heather|first=Peter|title=The Fall of the Roman Empire: A New History of Rome and the Barbarians|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=2007|isbn=0-195-32541-9
*cite book |title=Proceedings of the 21st International Congress of Byzantine Studies |last=Jakoby |first=David |editor=Elizabeth Jeffreys and F. K. Haarer|year=2006 |publisher=Ashgate Publishing Ltd |location= |isbn=0-754-65740-X |chapter=The Economy of Late Byzantium - Some Considerations
*cite book |last=Laiou |first=Angeliki E. |authorlink= |coauthors= |title=The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 2)|year=2002 |publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|editor=Angeliki E. Laiou|chapter=Exchange and Trade, Seventh-Twelfth Centuries |url=http://www.doaks.org/EHB.html|chapterurl= http://www.doaks.org/EconHist/EHB36.pdf
*cite book |last=Laiou |first=Angeliki E. |authorlink= |coauthors= |title=The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 1)|year=2002 |publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|editor=Angeliki E. Laiou|chapter=The Agrarian Economy, Thirteenth-Fifteenth Centuries|url=http://www.doaks.org/EHB.html|chapterurl= http://www.doaks.org/EconHist/EHB15.pdf
*cite book |last=Laiou |first=Angeliki E. |authorlink= |coauthors= |title=The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 1)|year=2002 |publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|editor=Angeliki E. Laiou|chapter=Writing the Economic History of Byzantium|url=http://www.doaks.org/EHB.html|chapterurl= http://www.doaks.org/EconHist/EHB01.pdf
*cite book |last=Lefort|first=Jacques|authorlink= |coauthors= |title=The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 3)|year=2002 |publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|editor=Angeliki E. Laiou|chapter=The Rural Economy, Seventh-Twelfth Centuries|url=http://www.doaks.org/EHB.html|chapterurl= http://www.doaks.org/EconHist/EHB14.pdf
*cite book |last=Magdalino |first=Paul|authorlink= |coauthors= |title=The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 2)|year=2002 |publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|editor=Angeliki E. Laiou|chapter=Medieval Constantinople: Built Environment and Urban Development|url=http://www.doaks.org/EHB.html|chapterurl= http://www.doaks.org/EconHist/EHB20.pdf
*cite book |last=Matschke|first=Klaus-Peter|authorlink= |coauthors= |title=The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 2)|year=2002 |publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|editor=Angeliki E. Laiou|chapter=Commerce, Trade, Markets, and Money: Thirteenth-Fifteenth Centuries|url=http://www.doaks.org/EHB.html| chapterurl=http://www.doaks.org/EconHist/EHB37.pdf
*cite book |last=Morrisson|first=Cécile|title=The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 3)|year=2002 |publisher=Dumbarton Oaks|editor=Angeliki E. Laiou|chapter=Byzantine Money: Its Production and Circulation|url=http://www.doaks.org/EHB.html|chapterurl= http://www.doaks.org/EconHist/EHB42.pdf
*cite journal |last=Neumann |first=Iver. B. |year=2006 |month=August |title= Sublime Diplomacy: Byzantine, Early Modern, Contemporary |journal=Millennium: Journal of International Studies |volume=34 |issue=3 |pages=865–888 |id=ISSN 1569-2981 |url=http://www.clingendael.nl/publications/2005/20051200_cli_paper_dip_issue102.pdf |accessdate=2007-05-21 |doi= 10.1177/03058298060340030201
*cite book|last=Nicolle|first=David|title=Constantinople 1453: The End of Byzantium|publisher=Osprey Publishing|year=2000|isbn=1-841-76091-9
*cite book|last=Norwich|first=John Julius|title=A History of Venice|publisher=Vintage|year=1989|isbn=0-679-72197-5
*cite book|last=Norwich|first=John Julius|title=A Short History of Byzantium|publisher=Penguin|year=1998|isbn=0-14-025960-0
*cite book|last=Norwich|first=John Julius|title=Byzantium: The Decline and Fall | publisher=Knopf|year=1995|isbn=0-679-41650-1
*cite encyclopedia |last=Zakythinos|first=Dionysios|editor=Passas Ioannis|encyclopedia= Encyclopedia "The Helios"|title=The Character of the Economy |volume=VII |location=Athens|year=1945-1955

Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать реферат

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Byzantine–Arab Wars (780–1180) — Part of the Byzantine Arab Wars …   Wikipedia

  • Byzantine Empire — This article is about the medieval Roman empire. For other uses, see Byzantine (disambiguation). Roman Empire Βασιλεία Ῥωμαίων, Ῥωμανία Basileia Rhōmaiōn, Rhōmanía Imperium Romanum, Romania …   Wikipedia

  • Byzantine coinage — Numismatics Terminology Portal Currency …   Wikipedia

  • Economy —    Byzantium s (q.v.) economy was based chiefly on agriculture (q.v.), for most citizens of the empire were farmers. By the ninth century, farmers were free peasants (as reflected in the Farmer s Law [q.v.]), and remained such until the growth of …   Historical dictionary of Byzantium

  • Byzantine–Ottoman Wars — Infobox Military Conflict conflict=Byzantine Ottoman wars caption=Clockwise from top left: Walls of Constantinople, Ottoman Janissaries, Byzantine Flag, Ottoman Bronze Cannon. partof=|date=1299 to 1453 place=Asia Minor result=Decisive Ottoman… …   Wikipedia

  • Byzantine law — Byzantine Culture Art • Architecture • Gardens Literature • Music Aristocracy &am …   Wikipedia

  • Byzantine studies — is an interdisciplinary branch of the humanities that addresses the history, culture, religion, art, science, economy, and politics of the Byzantine Empire. The discipline s founder in Germany is considered to be the philologist Hieronymus Wolf,… …   Wikipedia

  • Byzantine Empire — the Eastern Roman Empire after the fall of the Western Empire in A.D. 476. Cap.: Constantinople. * * * Empire, southeastern and southern Europe and western Asia. It began as the city of Byzantium, which had grown from an ancient Greek colony… …   Universalium

  • Byzantine civilisation in the twelfth century — During the 12th century, the civilization of the Byzantine Empire experienced a period of intense change and development. This has led some historians to refer to a twelfth century Renaissance in Byzantine cultural and intellectual… …   Wikipedia

  • Byzantine navy — Infobox War Faction name= Byzantine Navy war= the Justinianic Wars, the Byzantine Arab Wars, the Rus Byzantine Wars, the Crusades and the Byzantine Ottoman wars caption= active= 330 1453 AD ideology= leaders= Byzantine Emperor (Commander in… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”