- Economic anthropology
Economic anthropology is a scholarly field that attempts to explain human economic behavior using the tools of both
economics andanthropology . It is practiced by anthropologists and has a complex relationship with economics. There are three major paradigms within the field of economic anthropology: formalism, substantivism and culturalism.Formalism
The formalist model is the one most closely linked to
neoclassical economics , definingeconomics as the study ofutility maximisation under conditions ofscarcity . As an attempt to use neoclassicaltheory to analyze subjects outside of its traditional purview, formalist economicanthropology can be linked withnew institutional economics . This approach usually makes the following central assumptions:*Individuals pursue utility (or
preference ) maximisation by choosing between alternative means. They will always choose alternatives that maximise theirutility (or that yields a given amount of utility for the least possible amount of inputs or effort required), often within specific informational ortransaction cost constraints.
*Individuals will do so based onrationality , using all "available"information to measure the cost and utility of each means and considering theopportunity costs involved compared to spending their time and effort on other utility maximising pursuits. Lack of information can be modelled asinformation asymmetry or as atransaction cost . Whether byconscious forethought ,instincts , ortradition s, individuals are able to undertake the relevantcalculation s. In order to make rational choices individuals will seek to obtain all relevant information up to a point where theopportunity cost of information-gathering equals the additional utility gained from having been able to make better informed choices.
*All individuals live under conditions of scarcity of means while at the same time having unlimited wants.
*Underlying individuals' pursuit of utility maximisation is the principle of diminishing marginal utility, meaning that additional resources allocated towards a particular end will tend to achieve that end less and less efficiently. Rationalactor s will allocate their resources first towards those opportunities that provide the greatest payoff for them, and as opportunities get used up, allocate them towards progressively less efficient ends.Some formalists use
game theory as a model of rationalbehavior under specific cultural or interpersonal constraints. Formalists such asRaymond Firth andHarold K. Schneider assert that the neoclassical model of economics can be applied to anysociety if appropriate modifications are made, arguing that theprinciple s outlined above have universal validity. Allhuman culture s are therefore a collection of "choice making individuals whose every action involves conscious or unconscious selections among alternatives means to alternative ends" (Burling, 1962, quoted from Prattis, 1982:207), cite journal|author=Prattis, J. I.|title=Synthesis, or a New Problematic in Economic Anthropology|journal=Theory and Society | volume=11|pages=205–228|year=1982|id=|doi=10.1007/BF00158741] whereby the ends are culturally defined goals. Goals refer not only to economic value or financial gain but to anything that is valued by the individual, be it leisure, solidarity or prestige.In the context of hunter-gatherer and Neolithic cultures, formalist models usually must deal with high
transaction costs and are thus sometimes simplified to a model ofbilateral monopoly .Since a formalist model usually states what is to be maximized in terms of
preferences , which often but not necessarily include culturally expressed value goals, it is deemed to be sufficiently abstract to be capable of explaininghuman behavior in any context. A traditional assumption many formalists borrow from neoclassical economics is that the individual will make rational choices based on full information, or information that is incomplete in a specific way, in order to maximize whatever that individual considers being of value. While preferences may vary or change, and information about choices may or may not be complete, the principles of economising and maximising still apply.The role of the anthropologist may then be to analyse each culture in regards to its culturally appropriate means of attaining culturally recognized and valued goals. Individual preferences may differ from culturally recognized goals, and under economic rationality assumptions individual decisions are guided by individual preferences in an environment constrained by culture, including the preferences of others. Such an analysis should uncover the culturally-specific principles that underlie the rational decision-making process. In this way, economic theory has been applied by anthropologists to societies without price-regulating markets (e.g. Firth, 1961; Laughlin, 1973). Besides cultural values, formalists may also use
evolutionary psychology to help model preferences.ubstantivism
The substantivist position, first proposed by
Karl Polanyi in his work "The Great Transformation ", argues that the term 'economics' has two meanings: the formal meaning refers to economics as the logic of rational action and decision-making, as rational choice between the alternative uses of limited (scarce) means. The second, substantive meaning, however, presupposes neither rational decision-making nor conditions of scarcity. It simply refers to study of how humans make a living from their social andnatural environment . A society's livelihood strategy is seen as an adaptation to its environment and material conditions, a process which may or may not involve utility maximisation. The substantive meaning of 'economics' is seen in the broader sense of 'economising' or 'provisioning'. Economics is simply the way society meets their material needs.Polanyi's term "great transformation" refers to the divide between modern,
market -dominated societies andnon-Western ,non-capitalist pre-industrial societies. Polanyi argues that only the substantive meaning of economics is appropriate for analysing the latter. Without a system of price-making markets formal economic analysis does not apply, for example in centrally planned economies or preindustrial societies. Individual choice in such places is not so much based on the maximisation of economic profit but rather onsocial relationships ,cultural values ,moral concerns,politics orreligion . Production in mostpeasant and tribal societies is for the producers, also called 'production for use' or subsistence production, as opposed to 'production for exchange' which has profit maximisation as its chief aim. These types differ so radically that no single theory can describe them all.According to Polanyi, in modern capitalist economies the concepts of formalism and
substantivism coincide since people organise their livelihoods based on the principle of rational choice. However, in non-Capitalist, pre-industrial economies this assumption does not hold. Unlike their Western capitalist counterparts, they are not based on market exchange but onredistribution andreciprocity . Reciprocity is defined as the mutual exchange of goods or services as part of long-term relationships. Redistribution implies the existence of a strong political centre such askinship -basedleadership , which receives and then redistributes subsistence goods according to culturally-specific principles. In societies that are not market-based reciprocity and redistribution usually occur together. Conversely,market exchange is seen as the dominant mode of integration in modernindustrial societies , while reciprocity may continue in family and inter-household relations, and some redistribution is undertaken by the state or by charitable institutions. Each of these three systems of distribution requires a separate set of analytical concepts.Another key concept in substantivism is that of '
embeddedness '. Rather than being a separate and distinctsphere , the economy is embedded in both economic and non-economic institutions. Exchange takes place within and is regulated by society rather than being located in a socialvacuum . For example,religion andgovernment can be just as important to economics as economic institutions themselves. Socio-cultural obligations, norms and values play a significant role in people's livelihood strategies. Consequently, any analysis of economics as an analytically distinctentity isolated from its socio-cultural and political context is flawed from the outset. A substantivist analysis of economics will therefore focus on the study of the various socialinstitutions on which people's livelihoods are based. The market is only one amongst many institutions that determine the nature of economic transactions. Polanyi's central argument is that institutions are the primary organisers of economic processes. The substantive economy is an "instituted process of interaction between man and his environment, which results in a continuous supply of want satisfying material means" (1968:126).cite book|author=Polanyi, K.|title=The Economy as Instituted Process|publisher=in Economic Anthropology E LeClair, H Schneider (eds) New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston|year=1968|id=|isbn = 9780030717956]The concept of embeddedness has been very influential in the field of economic anthropology. In his study of Chinese ethnic
business network s inIndonesia ,Granovetter found individual's economic agency embedded in networks of strong personal relations. In processes of clientelization the cultivation of personal relationships between traders and customers assumes an equal or higher importance than the economic transactions involved. Economic exchanges are not carried out between strangers but rather by individuals involved in long-term continuing relationships. Granovetter describes theneo-liberal view of economic action as separating economics from society and culture, thereby promoting an 'undersocialized account' that atomises human behavior: "Actors do not behave or decide asatom s outside a social context, nor do they adhere slavishly to a script written for them by the particular intersection of social categories that they happen to occupy. Their attempts at purposive action are instead embedded in concrete, ongoing systems of social relations." (1985:487).cite journal|author=Granovetter, M.|title=Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness|journal=The American Journal of Sociology|volume=91|pages=481–510|year=1985|id=|doi=10.1086/228311]Culturalism
For some anthropologists the substantivist position does not go far enough in its criticism of the universal application of Western economic models on societies all around the globe.
Stephen Gudeman , for example, argues that the central processes of making a livelihood are culturally constructed. Therefore, models of livelihoods and related economic concepts such asexchange ,money orprofit must be analyzed through the locals' ways of understanding them. Rather than devising universal models rooting in Western understandings and using Western economic terminologies and then applying them indiscriminately to all societies, one should come to understand the 'local model'. In his work on livelihoods Gudeman seeks to present the "people's own economic construction" (1986:1);cite book|author=Gudeman, S.|title=Economics as culture : models and metaphors of livelihood|location=London|publisher=Routledge|year=1986|id=|isbn = 9780710205605] that is, not just examining the cultural construction of values as in which products people like to buy and how much they valueleisure , but people's own conceptualizations or mental maps of economics and its various aspects, i.e. their understanding of concepts such as exchange, property or profit. His description of a peasant community inPanama reveals that the locals did not engage in exchange with each other in order to make a profit but rather viewed it as an "exchange of equivalents", with the exchange value of a good being defined by the expenses spent on producing it. Only outside merchants made profits in their dealings with the community, and it was a complete mystery to the locals how they managed to do so...Gudeman not only rejects the formalist notion of the universal 'economic person'; he also criticizes the substantivist position for imposing their universal model of economics on all preindustrial societies and so making the same mistake as the formalists. While conceding that substantivism rightly emphasises the significance of social institutions in economic processes, Gudeman considers any derivational model that claims to be of universal nature, be it formalist, substantivist or Marxist, to be ethnocentric and essentially tautological. In his view they all model
human relationship s as mechanistic processes by taking the logic of natural science based on thematerial world and applying it to thehuman world . Rather than to "arrogate to themselves a privileged right to model the economies of their subjects", anthropologists should seek to understand and interpret local models (1986:38). Such local models may differ radically from their Western counterparts. To quote Gudeman: "Gaining a livelihood might be modelled as a causal and instrumental act, as a natural and inevitable sequence, as a result of supernatural dispositions or as a combination of all these." (1986:47). For example, the Iban only usehand knives toharvest rice . Even though the use ofsickles would speed up the harvesting process, their concern that thespirit of the rice may flee is greater than their desire to economize the harvesting process.Gudeman brings post-modern
cultural relativism to its logical conclusion. Generally speaking, however, culturalism can also be seen as an extension of the substantivist view, with a stronger emphasis on cultural constructivism, a more detailed account of local understandings andmetaphor s of economic concepts, and a greater focus on socio-cultural dynamics than the latter (cf. Hann, 2000).cite book|author=Hann, C. M.|title=Social Anthropology|location=London|publisher=Teach Yourself|year=2000|id=|isbn = 9780340724828] Culturalists also tend to be both less taxonomic and more culturally relativistic in their descriptions while critically reflecting on the power relationship between the ethnographer (or 'modeller') and the subjects of his or her research. While substantivists generally focus on institutions as their unit of analysis, culturalists lean towards detailed and comprehensive analyses of particular local communities. Both views agree in rejecting the formalist assumption that all human behaviour can be explained in terms of rational decision-making and utility maximisation.Critics of the Approaches
There have been many critics of the formalist position. Its central assumptions about human behavior have been questioned. In particular, it has been argued that the universality of rational choice and utility maximization cannot be assumed across all cultures. But also with regards to modern Western societies the economic reductionism in explaining human behaviour has been critiqued. Prattis notes that the premise of utility maximization is tautological; whatever a person does, may it be work or leisure, is declared to be utility maximization. If he or she doesn't maximize money then it must be pleasure or some other value. To quote: "This "post hoc" reasoning back to "
a priori " assumptions has minimal scientific value as it is not readily subject to falsification." (1989:212).cite book|author=Plattner, S.|title=Economic Anthropology|location=Stanford |Publisher=Stanford University Press|year=1989|id=|isbn = 9780804716451] For example, a person maysacrifice his or her owntime ,finance s or evenhealth to help others. Formalists would then pronounce that s/he does so due to placing a high value on helping others, and so sacrificing other goals in order to maximize this value and thereby to gain utility (e.g. meaning, satisfaction of having helped, approval from others etc.). But this is simply an assumption, the motivation of this person may or may not coincide with this inferred explanation pattern. Similarly, Gudeman argues that Western economic anthropologists will invariably "find" the people they study to behave "rationally" since that is what their model leads them to do. Conversely, formalism will consider any behavior that does not maximize utility based on available means as irrational. However, such "non-maximising acts" may seem perfectly rational and logical for the acting individual whose actions may have been motivated by a completely different set of meanings and understandings.Finally, there is the substantivist point that both economic institutions and individual economic activities are embedded in the socio-cultural sphere and can therefore not be analysed in isolation.
Social relationship s play an essential role in people's livelihood strategies; consequently, a narrow focus on atomised individual behavior to the exclusion of his or her socio-cultural context is bound to be flawed.Substantivism has not been without its critics, either. Prattis (1982) argues that the strict distinction between
primitive and modern economies in substantivism is problematic. Constraints on transactional modes are situational rather than systemic (he therefore implies that substantivism focuses on social structures at the expensive of analyzing individual agency). Non-maximizing adaptation strategies occur in all societies, not just in "primitive" ones. Similarly, Plattner (1989) argues that some generalization across different societies are still possible, meaning that Western and non-Western economics are not entirely different. In an age of globalization there are probably hardly any "pure" preindustrial societies left. Conditions of resource scarcity can be said to exist anywhere in the world. It is significant to note anthropological fieldwork that demonstrates rational behavior and complex economic choices amongst peasants (cf. Plattner, 1989:15). Also, individuals in e.g.communist societies can still engage in rational utility maximizing behavior, e.g. by building relationships tobureaucrat s who control distribution, or by using small plots of land in theirgarden to supplement officialfood ration s. Cook thinks that there are significant conceptual problems with the substantivists’ theorizing: "They define economics as an aspect of everything that provisions society but nothing that provisions society is defined as economic." (1973:809).Fact|date=February 2007While market exchange is dominant in the West, redistribution can also play a very significant role particularly in the more socialist or welfare-state Western societies such as
France ,Germany orSweden .State and charity or religious organizations collect donations and then distribute them to needy groups (or use the funds to offer free or inexpensive social services).Culturalism can also be criticized from various perspectives. Marxists would argue that culturalists are too idealistic in their notion of the social construction of
reality and too weak in their analysis of external (i.e. material) constraints on individuals that affect their livelihood choices. If, as Gudeman argues, local models cannot be objectively appraised or held against a universal standard, then there is also no way of deconstructing them in terms of ideologies propagated by the powerful that serve to neutralise resistance through hegemony. This is further complicated by the fact that in an age ofglobalization most cultures are being integrated into the global capitalist system and are influenced to conform to Western ways of thinking and acting. Local and global discourses are mixing and the distinctions between the two are beginning to blur. Even though people will retain aspects of their existing worldviews, universal models can be used to study the dynamics of their integration into the rest of the world.German economists
Gunnar Heinsohn andOtto Steiger have acknowledged that market exchange is not universal and start from Karl Polanyi's distinction between systems based on reciprocity, redistribution and markets. However, they criticize both substantivists and formalists for being unable to provide a satisfactory explanation for market rationality and its historical origins. They developed a novel explanation for the origins of property, contracts, credit, money and markets that they term the "property theory of interest, money and markets" [Gunnar Heinsohn (2003): "Karl Polanyi's Failure to Exploit his Success: Why the Controversy between Substantivists and the Neoclassical Protagonists (Formalists) of an Eternal and Universal Market was Never Solved." [http://www.iksf.uni-bremen.de/symposium/downloads/G.Heins-Symp.pdf] (Paper presented at an [http://www.iksf.uni-bremen.de/symposium/index_symp_en.html International Symposium on the Economic Role of Property] at theUniversity of Bremen, 28-30 Nov. 2003); see also Gunnar Heinsohn, Otto Steiger (2007): "Money, Markets and Property". In: Giacomin, Alberto and Marcuzzo, Maria (Eds.): "Money and Markets. A doctrinal approach." New York: Routledge, pp. 59-79 ISBN 9780415384032; G. Heinsohn (1984): "Privateigentum, Patriarchat, Geldwirtschaft. Eine sozialtheoretische Rekonstruktion zur Antike". Frankfurt/M.: Suhrkamp ISBN 9783518280553; G. Heinsohn, Otto Steiger (1996): "Eigentum, Zins und Geld. Ungelöste Rätsel der Wirtschaftswissenschaft". Reinbek: Rohwolt ISBN 9783498029333 (English: "Property, Interest and Money", London: Routledge, forthcoming)] . They apply their model todevelopment economics , where an understanding of dynamic markets is essential since the task is to create them where they have not existed before. [Otto Steiger (2007): Property Rights and Economic Development: Two Views. Marburg: Metropolis ( [http://www.metropolis-verlag.de/Property-Rights-and-Economic-Development%3A-Two-Views/483/book.do forthcoming] )] .References
Further reading
* Earle, Timothy (2008). "economic anthropology," "
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics ", 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_E000009&q=Economic%20Anthropology%20&topicid=&result_number=1 Abstract.]
*
*
*ee also
*
Anthropological theories of value
*Wealth#The Anthropological view of Wealth
*Non-market economics
*Society for economic anthropology External links
* [http://sea.org.ohio-state.edu/ The Society for Economic Anthropology]
* [http://www.uiowa.edu/~anthro/chibnik.shtml Faculty Page of Michael Chibnik, Faculty Member and teacher of Economic Anthropology at The University of Iowa]
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.