- Great Depression in the United Kingdom
This article deals with the effects of the
Great Depression of the 1930s - also known as the Great Slump - on theUnited Kingdom .Background
The Great Depression of 1919–22 broke out at a time when Britain was still far from having recovered from the effects of the First World War.
Economist sHarold Cole andLee Ohanain show thateconomic output fell by 25% between 1918 and 1921 and did not recover until the end of the Great Depression [ Cole, Harold L. and Lee E. Ohanian, "The Great U.K. Depression a Puzzle and a Possible Resolution" in Kehoe, Prescott (2007)] , arguing that the United Kingdom suffered a twenty-year great depression beginning in 1918. Relative to the rest of the world, economic output declined mildly in the U.K. between 1929 and 1933.A major cause of financial instability, which preceded and accompanied the
Great Depression , was the debt that many European countries had accumulated to pay for their involvement in theGreat War . This debt destabilised many European economies as they tried to rebuild during the 1920s.Britain had largely avoided this trap by financing her war effort largely through sales of foreign assets. Britain had a net loss of £300 million of foreign investments, less than two years' investment on a pre-1914 average. [A. J. P. Taylor, "English History: 1914-1945" (OUP, 1990), p. 123.] The largest material loss during the war was in the
British Merchant Navy , which lost 40 percent of its merchant fleet to theU-boat attacks (but this was replaced soon after the war). [Ibid, p. 122.] Along with loss of assets through enemy action, such divestiture reduced British investments abroad by around 20% by 1918.The resulting loss of foreign earnings left the British economy more dependent upon
export s, and more vulnerable to any downturn in world markets. But the war had permanently eroded Britain's trading position in world markets through disruptions to trade and losses of shipping. Overseas customers for British produce had been lost, especially for traditional exports such astextiles ,steel andcoal .The 1920s saw the development of new industries such as the
motor industry and the electrical goods industry, but British products in these fields were not usually sufficiently advanced to compete in world markets against foreign competitors possessing more up-to-date plants, and so British products largely served the domestic market.The traditional industries which formed the bedrock of Britain's export trade (such as coalmining,
shipbuilding and steel) were heavily concentrated in certain areas of Britain, such as theNorth of England ,South Wales and centralScotland , while the newer industries were heavily concentrated in southern and central England.Altogether, British industrial output during the 1920s ran at about 80-100%, and exports at about 80% of their pre-war levels Constantine, Stephen. (1980) "Unemployment in Britain Between the Wars", Longman, ISBN 0-582-35232-0] , so there was little chance of Britain being able to amass enough capital to restore her overseas investment position.
The Gold Standard & the General Strike
From about 1921, Britain had started a slow economic recovery from the war and the subsequent slump. But in April 1925 the Conservative Chancellor,
Winston Churchill , on advice from theBank of England , restored thePound Sterling to thegold standard at its prewarexchange rate of 4.86 US dollars. This made the pound convertible to its value ingold , but at a level that made British exports more expensive on world markets. The economic recovery was immediately slowed. To offset the effects of the highexchange rate , the export industries tried to cut costs by lowering workers' wages, provoking the General Strike of May 1926 [ [http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/events/budget_99/budget_briefing/279928.stm Budget blunders] bbc.co.uk] . The industrial areas of Britain spent the rest of the 1920s inrecession , and these industries received little investment or modernisation. Throughout the 1920sunemployment stayed at a steady one million.Economic Crisis and the Labour government 1929-1931
In May 1929 a minority Labour government headed by
Ramsay MacDonald came to office with Liberal support. This was only the second time a Labour government had been in office (they had briefly been in office in 1924), and few of the government's members had any deep knowledge ofeconomics or experience of running the economy. MacDonald's Labour Party was notradical in economic thinking, and was wedded to the orthodoxy of Victorianclassical economics with its emphasis on maintaining abalanced budget at any cost.In October 1929 the Stock Market Crash in
New York heralded theGreat Depression . The ensuing American economic collapse shook the world: World trade contracted, prices fell and governments faced financial crisis as the supply of American credit dried up. Many countries adopted an emergency response to the crisis by erecting trade barriers andtariff s, which worsened the crisis by further hindering global trade.The effects on the industrial areas of Britain were immediate and devastating, as demand for British products collapsed. By the end of 1930
unemployment had more than doubled from 1 million to 2.5 million (20% of the insured workforce), and exports had fallen in value by 50%. Government revenues contracted as national income fell, while the cost of assisting the jobless rose. The industrial areas were hardest hit, along with thecoal mining districts. London and the south-east of England were hurt less. In 1933, 30% of Glaswegians were unemployed due to the severe decline in heavy industry.Under pressure from its Liberal allies as well as the Conservative opposition, the Labour government appointed a committee to review the state of public finances. The
May Report of July 1931 urgedpublic sector wage cuts and large cuts in public spending (notably in benefit payments to the unemployed) to avoid incurring a budget deficit. This proposal proved deeply unpopular within the Labour Party and among its main supporters, thetrade union s, which along with several government ministers refused to support any such measures. TheChancellor of the Exchequer ,Philip Snowden , insisted that the Report's recommendations be adopted to avoid incurring a budget deficit. In amemorandum in January 1930, one junior government minister,Oswald Mosley , proposed that the government should take control ofbanking and exports, as well as increasepension s to boost purchasing power. When his ideas were turned down, he resigned. He soon left Labour to form the New Party, and later theBritish Union of Fascists .The National Government
The dispute over spending and wage cuts split the Labour government: as it turned out, beyond recovery. The resulting political deadlock caused investors to take fright, and a flight of
capital andgold further de-stabilised the economy. In response, MacDonald, on the urging of King George V, decided to form a "National Government" with the Conservatives and the Liberals. On 24 August MacDonald submitted the resignation of his ministers and led his senior colleagues in forming the new National Government. MacDonald and his supporters were expelled from the Labour Party and adopted the label "National Labour". The Labour Party and some Liberals, led byDavid Lloyd George , went into opposition. The Labour Party denounced MacDonald as a "traitor" and a "rat" for what they saw as his betrayal.Soon after this, a
General Election was called. The election resulted in a Conservative landslide victory, with the now leaderless Labour Party winning only 46 seats in Parliament. After the 1931 election the national government became Conservative-dominated, although MacDonald continued asPrime Minister until 1935.Emergency measures
In an effort to balance the budget and restore confidence in the pound, on the 10 September 1931 with
Phillip Snowden still as Chancellor, the new national government issued an emergencybudget , which immediately instituted a round of cuts in public spending and wages. Public sector wages and unemployment pay were cut by 10%, andincome tax was raised from 4s 6d to 5s in the pound [Taxes raised in the Finance (No. 2) Bill, passed into law in October. See copy of the bill in "The Times", September 19, 1931] (from 22.5% to 25%). The pay cuts did not go down well however and resulted in a Mutiny in theRoyal Navy .These measures were
deflation ary and merely reduced purchasing power in the economy, worsening the situation, and by the end of 1931 unemployment had reached nearly 3 million. Constantine, Stephen (1983) "Social Conditions in Britain 1918-1939" ISBN 0-416-36010-6] . The measures were also unsuccessful at defending the gold standard, which the National Government had ostensibly been created to defend.Because of the
gold standard there was nothing to stop a flight of gold. At first the government tried to stop the flight by introducing punitiveinterest rates . However panic among international investors following the Mutiny, put renewed pressure on the pound, and on 21 September 1931 the government was finally forced to abandon the gold standard, and immediately the exchange rate of the pound fell by 25%, from $4.86 to $3.40. This eased the pressure on exporters, and laid the ground for a gradual economic recovery.Also, in 1932 following the
Ottawa Agreement Neville Chamberlain who had become Chancellor after the 1931 election, introducedtariff s on imports at a rate of 10% on all imports except those from the countries of theBritish Empire . The introduction of tarrifs caused a a split in the Liberal Party, some of whom, along with Phillip Snowden withdrew support for the National Government.Britain in the 1930s: a nation divided
Although the overall picture for the British economy in the 1930s was bleak, the effects of the depression were uneven. Some parts of the country, and some industries, fared better than others. Some parts of the country such as the
South Wales Valleys , experienced mass unemployment and poverty, while some areas in theHome Counties did not.The South and the Midlands
Although in
London and the south east of England unemployment was initially as high as 13.5%, the later 1930s were a prosperous time in these areas, as asuburban house-building boom was fuelled by the low interest rates which followed the abolition of the gold standard, and as London's growing population buoyed the economy of theHome Counties .The south was also the home of new developing industries such as the electrical industry, which prospered from the large-scale electrification of housing and industry.
Mass production methods brought new products such as electricalcooker s,washing machine s andradio s into the reach of themiddle class es, and the industries which produced these prospered. Nearly half of all new factories that opened in Britain between 1932 and 1937 were in thegreater London area.Another industry that prospered during the 1930s was the British
motor industry . For cities that had a developed motor industry such asBirmingham ,Coventry andOxford , the 1930s were also a boom time. Manufacturers such as Austin, Morris and Ford dominated the motor industry during the 1930s, and the number of cars on British roads doubled within the decade. BritishAgriculture also flourished in the 1930s.The North and other industrial areas
The
North of England however was a quite different matter. The north was the home to most of Britain's traditional heavy industries such ascoal mining inYorkshire andNottinghamshire ,shipbuilding onTyneside ,steel inSheffield andtextile s inLancashire which were heavilyexport orientated. The north bore the brunt of the depression, and the '30s were the most difficult time in living memory for people in these areas. The north was hit so hard in the Great Depression because of the structural decline in British industry. Staple industries such as coal, steel and shipbuilding were smaller, less modern and efficient and over-staffed compared to continental rivals.In the north east (including
Sunderland ,Middlesbrough andNewcastle-upon-Tyne ) this was especially so. The north east was traditionally a major centre of the shipbuilding industry. The Depression caused a collapse in demand for ships. Between 1929 and 1932 ship production declined by 90%, and this in turn affected all the supply industries such as steel and coal. In some towns and cities in the north east, unemployment reached as high as 70%. Among the worst affected towns wasJarrow , where unemployment led to the famousJarrow March , in which unemployed workers marched 300 miles to London to protest against unemployment.The north west, a traditional centre of the textile industries, was also hard hit, with places such as
Manchester andLancashire suffering a slump. SouthWales , a centre of the coalmining and steel industries, was also devastated by the depression where towns such asMerthyr Tydfil andSwansea had unemployment rates reaching above 25% at certain times . The industrial belt of centralScotland , also a major shipbuilding centre inGlasgow , was also hard hit by the slump.In these areas millions of unemployed and their families were left destitute, and queueing at
soup kitchen s became a way of life. A government report in the mid 1930s estimated that around 25% of the UK's population existed on asubsistence diet, often with signs of childmalnutrition such asScurvy ,Rickets andTuberculosis . In his book "The Road to Wigan Pier ",George Orwell described life for the unemployed in northern England during the depression: "Several hundred men risk their lives and several hundred women scrabble in the mud for hours... searching eagerly for tiny chips ofcoal in slagheaps so they could heat their own homes. For them, this arduously-gained 'free' coal was more important almost than food."The welfare state during the 1930s
In the 1920s and 1930s Britain had a relatively advanced welfare system compared to many of the industrialised countries. In 1911 a compulsory national unemployment and health insurance scheme had been put in place by the Liberal government of Herbert Henry Asquith (see
Liberal reforms ). This scheme had been funded through contributions from the government, the employers and the workers. At first the scheme only applied to certain trades but, in 1920, it was expanded to include most manual workers.However, the scheme only paid out according to the level of contributions made rather than according to need, and was only payable for 15 weeks. Anyone unemployed for longer than that had to rely on
poor law relief paid by their local authority. In effect, millions of workers who had been too poorly paid to make contributions, or who had been unemployed long term, were left destitute by the scheme. With the mass unemployment of the 1930s, contributions to the insurance scheme dried up, resulting in a funding crisis.In August 1931, the 1911 scheme was replaced by a fully government-funded
unemployment benefit system [ [http://www2.rgu.ac.uk/publicpolicy/introduction/historyf.htm rgu.ac.uk] ] . This system, for the first time, paid out according to need rather than the level of contributions. This unemployment benefit was subject to a strictmeans test , and anyone applying for unemployment pay had to have an inspection by a government official to make sure that they had no hidden earnings or savings, undisclosed source(s) of income or other means of support. For many poor people this was a humiliating experience and was much resented.low recovery
Following Britain's withdrawal from the gold standard and the devaluation of the pound, interest rates were reduced from 6% to 2%. As a result, British exports became more competitive on world markets than those of countries that remained on the gold standard. This led to a modest economic recovery, and a fall in unemployment from 1933 onwards. Although exports were still a fraction of their pre-depression levels, they recovered slightly.
Unemployment began a modest fall in 1934 and fell further in 1935 and 1936, but the rise in employment levels occurred mostly in the south, where lower interest rates had spurred the house building boom, which in turn spurred a recovery in domestic industry. The North and Wales remained severely depressed for most of the decade. In severely depressed parts of the country, the government enacted a number of policies to stimulate growth and reduce unemployment, including road building, loans to shipyards, and tariffs on steel imports. These policies helped but were not, however, on a sufficiently large scale to make a huge impact on the unemployment levels.
Rearmament and recovery
From 1936 onwards the National Government followed a policy of mass rearmament in the face of the rise of
Nazi Germany . This provided the economic stimulus that finally ended the depression. By 1937 unemployment had fallen to 1.5 million, from where it fell even further. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak ofWorld War II in September 1939 finally ended unemployment.Consequences of the Great Depression
Following the end of
World War II , the majority of the British people, and particularly theworking class and returning servicemen and women, did not want a return to pre-war Conservative economic policies, which they blamed for the hardship of the 1930s, and there was a mood for widespread social change. At the 1945 general election, to the surprise of many observers,Winston Churchill was defeated by the Labour Party headed byClement Attlee .The Labour government presided over the foundation of a comprehensive 'cradle-to-grave'
welfare state , and founded a universal, tax fundedNational Health Service , which gave treatment according to need rather than ability to pay. The Labour government also enactedKeynesian economic policies, to stimulate the economy to createfull employment . These policies became known as the "post-war consensus ", and were accepted by all major political parties. This post-war consensus lasted until the late 1970s when it came under attack from the Conservatives led byMargaret Thatcher .Historic evaluation
The events of the 1930s, and the response of the Labour and National governments to the depression, have generated much historical controversy.
In the decades immediately following World War II most historical opinion was critical of the governments of the period. Certain historians, such as
Robert Skidelsky in his "Politicians and the Slump", compared the orthodox policies of the Labour and National governments unfavourably with the more radical proto-Keynesian measures advocated byLloyd George andOswald Mosley , and the more interventionist and Keynesian responses in other economies:Franklin Roosevelt 'sNew Deal in theUnited States , the Labour government inNew Zealand , and the Social Democratic government inSweden . Since the 1970s opinion has become less uniformly hostile. In the preface to the 1994 edition Skidelsky argues that recent experience of currency crises and capital flight make it hard to be so critical of the politicians who wanted to achieve stability by cutting labour costs and defend the value of the currency.References
* Aldcroft, D. H. "The British Economy. Volume 1: The Years of Turmoil, 1920-1951", Wheatsheaf.(1986)
* Booth, A. and Pack, M. (1985) "Employment, Capital and Economic Policy in Great Britain 1918-1939" Blackwell.
* Bowley M. (1947), "Housing and the State 1919-1944", Allen & Unwin.
* Broadberry S. N. (1986), "The British Economy between the Wars", Basil Blackwell.
* Buxton, N. K. and Aldcroft, D. H. (1979) "British Industry between the Wars: Instability and Industrial Development, 1919-1939", Scolar Press.
* S. Constantine, "Unemployment in Britain Between the Wars" (1980).
* S. Constantine, (1983) "Social Conditions in Britain 1918-1939" ISBN 0-416-36010-6
* A. Crowther, British Social Policy, 1914-1939 (1988).
* Roderick Floud and Donald McCloskey (eds.), "The Economic History of Britain since 1700" Cambridge University Press.
* Garraty, John A., "The Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by Contemporaries and in Light of History" (1986)
* Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott. " [http://www.greatdepressionsbook.com Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century] " Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 2007.
* Nick, Smart, "National Government 1931-40" (1999) MacMillan Press Ltd
* George Orwell, "The Road to Wigan Pier" (1937).
* Richardson H. W. (1967), "Economic Recovery in Britain 1932-39" , Weidenfeld & Nicolson
* Richardson H. W. ( 1962), "'The basis of economic recovery in the 1930s: a review and a new interpretation'", Economic History Review.
* Robbins L. (1934), "The Great Depression", Macmillan.
* Skidelsky R. (1967), "Politicians and the Slump: The Labour Government of 1929-33" Macmillan.
* J. Stevenson, and C. Cook, "The Slump" (1977).
* A. J. P. Taylor, "English History: 1914-1945" (OUP, 1990)
*A. Thorpe, (1992) "Britain in the 1930s", BlackwellNotes
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.