Two-part tariff

Two-part tariff

A two-part tariff is a price discrimination technique in which the price of a product or service is composed of two parts - a lump-sum fee as well as a per-unit charge. As with all price discrimination techniques, it may only occur in partially or fully monopolistic markets. It is designed to enable the firm to capture more consumer surplus than it otherwise would in a non-discriminating pricing environment.

Depending on the homogeneity of demand, the lump-sum fee charged varies, but the rational firm will set the per unit charge above or equal to the marginal cost of production, and below or equal to the price the firm would charge in a perfect monopoly.

An important element to remember concerning two-part tariffs is that it is still price discrimination, of which an important feature is that the product or service offered by the firm must be identical to all consumers, hence, price charged may vary, but "not due to different costs borne by the firm", as this would infer a differentiated product. Thus, while credit cards which charge an annual fee plus a per-transaction fee is a good example of a two-part tariff, a fixed fee charged by a car rental company in addition to a per-kilometre fuel fee is not so good, because the fixed fee may reflect fixed costs such as registration and insurance which the firm must recoup in this manner. This can make the identification of two-part tariffs difficult.

A two-part tariff when consumer demand is homogeneous

When consumers have homogeneous demand, any one consumer is representative of the market (the market being n identical consumers). For purposes of demonstration, consider just one consumer who interacts with one firm which experiences no fixed costs and constant costs per unit - hence the horizontal marginal cost (MC) line.

Recall that the demand curve represents our consumer’s maximum willingness to pay for any given output. Thus, as long as he receives an appropriate amount of goods, such as Qc, then he will be willing to pay his entire surplus (ABC) in addition to the cost per unit under perfect competition (Pc by Qc) - i.e. the entire area under the demand curve up to point Qc.

If the firm is perfectly competitive, it would charge price Pc and supply Qc to our consumer, making no economic profit but producing an allocatively efficient output. If the firm is a "non-price discriminating" monopolist, it would charge price Pm per unit and supply Qm, maximizing profit but producing below the allocatively efficient level of output Qc. This situation yields economic profit for the firm equal to the green area B, consumer surplus equal to the light blue area A, and a deadweight loss equal to the purple area C.

If the firm is a "price discriminating" monopolist, then it has the capacity to extract more resources from the consumer. It charges a lump sum fee, as well as a per unit cost. In order to sell the maximum number of units, the firm must charge the perfectly competitive price per unit, Pc, because this is the only price at which Qc units can be sold (note this is also the marginal cost per unit). To make up for the lower cost per unit, the firm then imposes a fee upon our consumer equal to her consumer surplus, ABC.

The lump-sum fee enables the firm to capture all the consumer surplus and deadweight loss areas, resulting in higher profit than a non-price discriminating monopolist could manage. The result is a firm which is in a sense allocatively efficient (price per unit is equal to marginal cost, but total price is not) - one of the redeeming qualities of price discrimination. If there are multiple consumers with homogeneous demand, then profit will equal n times the area ABC, where n is the number of consumers.

A two-part tariff when consumer demand is different

We now consider the case where there are two consumers, X and Y. Consumer Y's demand is exactly twice consumer X's demand, and each of these consumers is represented by a separate demand curve, and their combined demand (Dmarket). The firm is the same as in the previous example. We assume that the firm "cannot separately identify each consumer" - it cannot therefore price discriminate against each of them individually.

The firm would like to follow the same logic as before and charge a per-unit price of Pc while imposing a lump-sum fee equal to area ABCD - the largest consumer surplus of the two consumers. In so doing, however, the firm will be pricing consumer X out of the market, because the lump-sum fee far exceeds his own consumer surplus of area AC.

Nevertheless, this would still yield profit equal ABCD. A solution to pricing consumer X out of the market is to thus charge a lump-sum fee equal to area AC, and continue to charge Pc per unit. Profit in this instance equals twice the area AC (two consumers): since consumer Y's demand is twice consumer X's, then 2 x AC = ABCD. As it turns out, the producer is indifferent to either of these pricing possibilities.

However, it is possible for the firm to earn even greater profits. Assume it sets the unit price equal to Pm, and imposes a lump-sum fee equal to area A. Both consumers again remain in the market, except now the firm is making a profit on each unit sold - total market profit from the sale of Qm units at price Pm is equal to area CDE. Profit from the lump-sum fee is 2 x A = AB. Total profit is therefore area ABCDE.

Thus, by charging a higher per unit price and a lower lump-sum fee, the firm has generated area E more profit than if it had charged a lower per-unit price and a higher lump-sum fee. Note that the firm is no longer producing the allocatively efficient output, and there is a deadweight loss experienced by society equal to area F - this is a result of the exercise of monopoly power.

Consumer X is left with no consumer surplus, while Consumer Y is left with area B.

Examples of two-part tariffs

The following items could be identified as two part tariffs; but it is possible some of them could be debated on the basis of the presence of fixed costs such as insurance which the firm cannot recoup in any other way.

* "membership discount retailers" such as shopping clubs that charge an annual fee for admission to the point of sale and also charge for your purchases
* amusement parks where there are admission fees and also per-ride fees
* cover charge for bars combined with per drink fees
* credit cards which charge an annual fee plus a per-transaction fee
* loyalty cards or clubs
* landline telephones where there is a fee to use the service ('line rental') and also a fee per call. The line rental covers the cost of providing the service, the per minute charge covers the cost of placing the call on the network.
* personal seat licenses in professional sports, in which fans of a team pay an up-front lump sum fee for the right to purchase tickets at face value

References

*cite book
first = Don E.
last = Waldman
year = 2004
title = Microeconomics
chapter = 12.2 Two-Part Tariffs, Bundling and Tying
pages = 332-335
publisher = Pearson Addison Wesley
id = ISBN 0-201-65877-1

ee also

*Microeconomics
*Pricing
*Price discrimination


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно сделать НИР?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • tariff — 1) Any list of charges for goods or services. 2) A tax or customs duty payable on imports or exports, or a list detailing such duties. The Customs and Excise issue tariffs stating which goods attract duty and what the rate of duty is. 3) A list… …   Big dictionary of business and management

  • Tariff — For other uses, see Tariff (disambiguation). Taxation An aspect of fiscal policy …   Wikipedia

  • Tariff (criminal law) — Under the criminal law of England and Wales, a tariff is the minimum period that a person serving an indefinite prison sentence must serve before that person becomes eligible for parole. The Home Secretary (or one of his/her delegates) bears… …   Wikipedia

  • part company — phrasal 1. a. : to bring a companionship, association, or similar connection between two parties (as individuals, groups, or organizations) to an end a faint diverging path was reached, where they parted company Thomas Hardy held the federal… …   Useful english dictionary

  • Feed-in tariff — Part of a series on Green economics Concepts …   Wikipedia

  • Morrill Tariff — The Morrill Tariff of 1861 was a protective tariff in the United States, adopted on March 2, 1861 during the administration of President James Buchanan. Named for its sponsor, Representative Justin Smith Morrill of Vermont, who drafted it with… …   Wikipedia

  • Whole life tariff — The whole life tariff is a mechanism in British law whereby a prisoner is sentenced to remain in prison until his or her death. It came into force in 1983 when the British Home Secretary began to set minimum terms that convicted killers had to… …   Wikipedia

  • Двухчастный тариф — TWO PART TARIFF Метод ценообразования на основе двойной ставки: платы за единицу потребляемого продукта плюс фиксированная ежегодная или ежеквартальная плата для покрытия накладных расходов. Компании, применяющие такие тарифы, стремятся… …   Словарь-справочник по экономике

  • Price discrimination — or price differentiation[1] exists when sales of identical goods or services are transacted at different prices from the same provider.[2] In a theoretical market with perfect information, perfect substitutes, and no transaction costs or… …   Wikipedia

  • Channel coordination — (or supply chain coordination) aims at improving supply chain performance by aligning the plans and the objectives of individual enterprises. It usually focuses on inventory management and ordering decisions in distributed inter company settings …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”