- Employment Protection Legislation
Employment Protection Legislation (EPL) refers to all types of employment protection measures, whether grounded primarily in legislation, court rulings, collectively bargained conditions of employment or customary practice [OECD Employment Outlook, June 1999, Chapter 2, "Employment Protection and Labour Market Performances", page 50.] . It is another term for
labour law , common among circles ofeconomist s. Employment protection refers both to regulations concerning hiring (e.g. rules favouring disadvantaged groups, conditions for using temporary or fixed-term contracts, training requirements) and firing (e.g. redundancy procedures, mandated prenotification periods and severance payments, special requirements for collective dismissals and short-time work schemes).There exist various institutional arrangements that can provide employment protection: the private market, labour legislation, collective bargaining arrangements and not the least, court interpretations of legislative and contractual provisions. Some forms of de facto regulations are likely to be adopted even in the absence of legislation, simply because both workers and firms derive advantages from long-term employment relations [OECD Employment Outlook, June 1999, Chapter 2, "Employment Protection and Labour Market Performances", page 51.] .
What is Employment Protection Legislation?
According to Barone (2001) [Barone, Andrea (2001): "Employment protection legislation: a critical review of the literature". Taken from www.cesifin.it [http://www.cesifin.it/doc?_FP_REP_ID=000069.barone%20copy.pdf&_VP_MAIN_OBJECT_TW_NAME=com.twproject.content.CONTENT] .] with the acronym EPL economists refer to the entire set of regulations that place some limits to the faculties of firms to hire and fire workers, even if they are not grounded primarily in the law, but originate from the
collective bargaining of the social partners, or are a consequence ofcourt ruling s. In particular, provisions favouring the employment of disadvantaged groups in society, determining the conditions for the use of temporary orfixed-term contract s, or imposing training requirements on the firm, affect hiring policies, while redundancy procedures, mandated pre-notification periods andseverance payment s, special requirements forcollective dismissal s and short-time work schemes influence firing decisions. The nature of these restrictions on the firms’ freedom to adjust the labour input is quite similar in all OECD countries, but the actual procedural details and the overall degree of stringency implied by them varies considerably. These provisions are enforced through the worker’s right to appeal against his lay-off.Some aspects of these regulations, like the length of advance notices or the dimension of severance payments can be measured with precision. Other important features of EPL, like for example the willingness of labour courts to entertain appeals by fired workers, or how judges interpret the concept of “just cause” for termination, are much more difficult to quantify.
The Employment Protection Legislation Index by the OECD
One of the more frequently used measures of the strictness of the EPL in each country and through different years is the so-called Employment Protection Legislation Index elaborated by the
OECD . This index is calculated along 18 basic items, which can be classified in three main areas [For a detailed description of this procedure, see OECD, Employment Outlook 1999, Chapter 2, Annex 2.B.] :
# Employment protection of regular workers against individual dismissal;
# Specific requirements for collective dismissals; and
# Regulation of temporary forms of employment.The 18 first-digit inputs are then expressed in either of the following forms:
# Units of time (e.g. delays before notice can start, or months of notice and severance pay);
# As a number (e.g. maximum number of successive fixed-term contracts allowed); or
# As a score on an ordinal scale specific to each item (0 to 2, 3, 4 or simply yes/no).Then, these different scoring is converted into cardinal scores that are normalized to range from 0 to 6, with higher scores representing stricter regulation. Therefore, each of the different items is normalized according to weighted averages, thus constructing three sets of summary indicators that correspond to successively more aggregated measures of EPL strictness.
The last step of the procedure involves computing, for each country, an overall summary indicator based on the three subcomponents:
#Strictness of regulation for regular contracts,
#Temporary contracts, and
#Collective dismissals.The summary measure for collective dismissals is attributed just 40% of the weight assigned to regular and temporary contracts. The rational for this is that the collective dismissals indicator only reflects additional employment protection trigged by the collective nature of the dismissal. In most countries, these additional requirements are quite modest. Moreover, summary measures for collective dismissals are only available since the late 1990s. An alternative overall index, so-called Version 1, has been thus calculated as an unweighted average of the summary measures for regular and temporary contracts only. While more restrictive than the previous one (so-called Version 2), this alternative measure of the overall EPL strictness allows comparisons over a longer period of time (since the late 1980s compared with the late 1990s) [OECD Employment Outlook 2004, Chapter 2, "Employment Protection Regulation and Labour Market Performance".] .
Effects of Employment Protection Legislation
On the duality of the labour market
There exists agreement among economists on the empirical evidence giving support to the theories according to which EPL leads to a segmentation in the
labour market between the so-called "insiders", the workers with a protected job, and the "outsiders", who are people that are either unemployed or employed with fixed-term, part-time or temporary contracts, or even in theblack economy , and face big difficulties to find a job covered by EPL because of the firms’ reduced propensity to hire. This latter group is mainly constituted by youths, women, racial minorities and unskilled workers [Barone, Andrea (2001): "Employment protection legislation: a critical review of the literature". Taken from www.cesifin.it [http://www.cesifin.it/doc?_FP_REP_ID=000069.barone%20copy.pdf&_VP_MAIN_OBJECT_TW_NAME=com.twproject.content.CONTENT] .] .On unemployment
Whether EPL has any effect on unemployment is an issue of contention between economists. On the one hand, assuming that the cyclical wage pattern is not affected by mandated firing costs, EPL reduces the propensity to hire by employers, since they fear that such decisions will be difficult to reverse in the future, in case of a recession. On the other hand, EPL also leads firms during downswings to keep more workers employed, than they would have otherwise done. Therefore, EPL reduces both
job creation andjob destruction , so that the net effects on averageemployment andunemployment are not identifiable a priori. What is instead agreed among economists, is that more stringent EPL lowers thefluctuation s in the quantity of labourdemand ed over thebusiness cycle , leading to smoother dynamic patterns of those aggregates [Barone, Andrea (2001): "Employment protection legislation: a critical review of the literature". Taken from www.cesifin.it [http://www.cesifin.it/doc?_FP_REP_ID=000069.barone%20copy.pdf&_VP_MAIN_OBJECT_TW_NAME=com.twproject.content.CONTENT] .] .Economists considering that EPL has no effect on unemployment include Blanchard and Portugal (2000) [Blanchard, O. and Pedro Portugal (2000): "What hides behind an unemployment rate: Comparing Portuguese and U.S. labor markets". The American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 1. (Mar., 2001), pp. 187-207.] . In their article they compare two opposite countries as regards their EPL stance:
Portugal with one of the more strict legislations in the world and theUS with one of the more flexible ones. In spite of these differences, both countries have similar unemployment rates which undermines the argument considering that EPL has any effect on unemployment. Instead, the authors claim that EPL does affect two other variables:job flows and unemployment duration. EPL would reduce job flows (from employment to unemployment: employers are less willing to fire, given that they must pay indemnizations to workers) therefore reducing unemployment but would increase unemployment duration, increasing the unemployment rate. These two effects would neutralize each other, explaining why overall, EPL has no effect on unemployment.Nickell (1997) [Nickell, Stephen (1997): "Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe versus North America". The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 3. (Summer, 1997), pp. 55-74.] arrived to similar conclusions when stating that labor market rigidities that do not appear to have serious implications for average levels of unemployment included strict employment protection legislation and general legislation on labor market standards.
Among those that have found evidence suggesting that EPL increases unemployment are Lazear (1990) [Lazear, Edward P. (1990): "Job Security Provisions and Employment". The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 3. (Aug., 1990), pp. 699-726.] . The author argued that mandated severance pay seemed to increase unemployment rates. His estimates suggested that an increase from zero to three months of severance pay would raise the unemployment rate by 5.5 percent in the United States.
On employment
Lazear (1990) [Lazear, Edward P. (1990): "Job Security Provisions and Employment". The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 105, No. 3. (Aug., 1990), pp. 699-726.] once again finds evidence suggesting that EPL reduces the
Employment-to-Population ratio . In his article he claims that the best estimates suggest that moving from no requiredseverance pay to three months of required severance pay to employees with ten years of service would reduce the employment-population ratio by about one percent. In theUnited States that would mean over a million jobs. The author affirms that the young could bear a disproportionate amount of the burden.To the contrary, Bertola and Bentolila (1990) [Bentolila, Samuel and Giuseppe Bertola (1990): "Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?". The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 57, No. 3. (Jul., 1990), pp. 381-402.] found evidence supporting the idea that firing costs have a larger effect on firms' propensity to fire than to hire, and therefore (slightly) increase average long-run
employment .On wages
Several authors have found that EPL has significant effects on wages. As stated by Lazear (1990) [Lazear, Edward (1990): "Job Security Provisions and Employment". Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(3): 699-726.] , in a perfect labor market, severance payments can have no real effects as they can be undone by a properly designed labor contract. Leonardi and Pica (2006) found evidence supporting this claim. They suggest that in the case of
Italy an EPL reform in 1990 had as effect to reduce entry wages by 6 percent, implying that firms tend to transfer the increase in the cost of firing (due to EPL) onto workers. In fact, in their study they find that 25 percent of the firing cost was shifted onto lower wages in the case of Italy [Leonardi, Marco and Giovanni Pica (2006): "Effects of Employment Protection Legislation on Wages: a Regression Discontinuity Approach". IZA Working Papers. Downloadable [http://www.iza.org/conference_files/TAM2006/pica_g1513.pdf] .] .On firm efficiency and profits
In principle the effects on profits are ambiguous. Because of EPL, firms engage themselves in labour hoarding practices, which lead them to employ a lower quantity of workers during upswings, while keeping inefficient levels of employment in downturns. For a given level of wages, this loss of productive
efficiency would result in lower averageprofit s. On the other hand, if firmsoperated in a context of efficiency wages, by inducing more stable relationships with the workers and reducing their job and income insecurity, EPL could allow them to pay lower wages, without reducing the effort provided by the labour force employed, with beneficial effects on profits [Barone, Andrea (2001): "Employment protection legislation: a critical review of the literature". Taken from www.cesifin.it [http://www.cesifin.it/doc?_FP_REP_ID=000069.barone%20copy.pdf&_VP_MAIN_OBJECT_TW_NAME=com.twproject.content.CONTENT] .] .On product market regulation
There appears to be agreement among economists on the positive
correlation between product market and employmentregulation . Although employment protection legislation is only one aspect of the wide range of regulatory interventions in thelabour market , Nicoletti et al (2000) find evidence suggesting that, across countries, restrictive regulatory environments in the product market tend to be associated with restrictive employment protection policies. They claim that the indicators presented in their paper are closely related, with a statisticalcorrelation of 0.73 (significant at the 1% level). In other words, according to these results, restrictive product market regulations are matched by analogous EPL restrictions to generate a tight overall regulatory environment for firms in their product market as well as in the allocation oflabour input s. The strong correlation between regulatory regimes inthe product market and EPL also suggests that their influence may have compounded effects on labour market outcomes, making regulatory reform in only one market less effective than simultaneous reform in the two markets [Nicoletti, Giuseppe; Stefano Scarpetta and Olivier Boylaud (2000): "Summary Indicators of Product Market Regulation with an Extension to Employment Protection Legislation". OECD Economics Department Working Papers NO. 226, April 13 2000, p.51. Downloadable [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/21/13/1880867.pdf] ] .Kugler and Pica (2003) find similar results in the case of the Italian economy. They present a matching model which illustrates how
barriers to entry in theproduct market (product market regulation) mitigate the impact oflabor market deregulation , (that is, mitigate the effects of a reduction in the strictness of EPL). In the author's opinion, this means that there are economic complementarities between labor and product market policies in their model, in the sense that the effectiveness of one policy depends on the implementation of the other policy. Thus, an important implication of their model is that labor market deregulation will be less effective in the presence of heavier regulations of entry [Kugler, Adriana and Giovanni Pica (2003): "Effects of Employment Protection and Product Market Regulations on the Italian Labor Market". Journal of Economic Literature, November 12, 2003, p. 7. Downloadable [http://www.uh.edu/~adkugler/lpmr51.pdf] .] . Similar results are obtained by Koeniger and Vindigni (2003) [Koeniger, Winfried and Andrea Vindigni (2003): "Employment Protection and Product Market Regulation". IZA WZB Economics Seminar Series. July 28, 2003. Downloadable [http://www.wz-berlin.de/mp/sem/past/2003/pap2003/koeniger.pdf] .] .On hours per worker
Whereas EPL may have not a significant effect on unemployment, strict EPL gives incentives to the firms to resort to other sources of flexibility like overtime, which, as shown by Abraham and Houseman (1994) [Abraham K.G. and Houseman S.N.(1994): "Does Employment Protection Inhibit Labour Market Flexibility? Lessons from Germany, France and Belgium". In Blank R.M. (ed.) "Social Protection versus Economic Flexibility: Is there a trade-off?". The University of Chicago Press, (1994)] , indeed tends to be used much more in Continental European countries, where the variability of hours per worker is significantly higher than in the Anglo-Saxon
labour market s.ee also
*
Labour law
*Labour market
*Labour market flexibility
*Microeconomics
* Important publications in labour economics
*Unemployment References
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.