Foundations of Economic Analysis

Foundations of Economic Analysis

Foundations of Economic Analysis is a book by Paul A. Samuelson published in 1947 (Enlarged ed., 1983). It sought to demonstrate a common mathematical structure underlying multiple branches of economics from two basic principles: optimizing behavior of agents and stability of equilibrium as to economic systems (such as markets or economies). Among other contributions, it advanced the theory of index numbers and generalized welfare economics. It is especially known for definitively stating and formalizing qualitative and quantitative versions of the "comparative statics" method for calculating how a change in any parameter (say, a change in tax rates) affects an economic system. One of its key insights about comparative statics, called the correspondence principle, states that stability of equilibrium implies testable predictions about how the equilibrium changes when parameters are changed.

Introduction

The front page quotes the motto of J. Willard Gibbs: "Mathematics is a language." With a portent of the author's gift for concision, the book begins::"The existence of analogies between central features of various theories implies the existence of a general theory which underlies the particular theories and unifies them with respect to those central features." This fundamental principle of generalization by abstraction was enunciated by the eminent American mathematician E. H. Moore more than thirty years ago. It is the purpose of the pages that follow to work out its implications for theoretical and applied economics.

Its other stated purpose (p. 3) is to show how "operationally meaningful theorems" can be described with a small number of "analogous methods". Thus, "a general theory of economic theories" (1983, p. xxvi).

Topical outline

The body of the book is 353 pages. Topics and applications covered (all in terms of theory) include the following.: Part I
* introduction
* equilibrium systems (such as for a market or economy)
* maximizing behavior (such as to profits by a firm and utility by a consumer) in the calculus: sales-tax increase on equilibrium for a firm
* comparative statics (changes in prices and quantities and other equilibrium variables when underlying conditions change)
* cost and production
* consumer's behavior
* transformations, elasticities, composite commodities, index numbers, and rationing
* cardinal utility, constancy of the marginal utility of income, and consumer's surplus
* welfare economics: Part II
* stability of equilibrium systems, dynamics (disturbances in equilibrium), and comparative statics : the Keynesian system
* linear and nonlinear systems: Malthusian and optimum population
* dynamics: the business cycle: endogenous models: mixed exogenous-endogenous theories: mixed systems of a linear-stochastic type
* conclusions (on neoclassical theory from Walras to hints of the future in "comparative dynamics")

Methods and analysis

The book attempts to show how its purposes can be parsimoniously and fruitfully met in the language of mathematics. In its original version as a dissertation submitted to the David A. Wells Prize Committee of Harvard University in 1941, it was subtitled "The Observational Significance of Economic Theory" (p. ix).

One unifying theme, on the striking formal similarities of analysis in seemingly diverse fields, occurred only in the course of writing on them -- from consumer's behavior and production economics of the firm to international trade, business cycles, and income analysis. It dawned on the aurhor that he was prodigal "in proving essentially the same theorems" over and over. His failure of initial intuition, so he suggests, might be less surprising in light of the few economic writings then extant concerned with formulating "meaningful theorems" -- hypotheses "about" empirical data -- that could conceivably be refuted "by" empirical data (pp. 3-5).

Samuelson (pp. 5, 21-24) finds three sources of meaningful theorems sufficient to illuminate his purposes:
* "maximizing behavior" of economic units (as to "utility" for a consumer and "profit" for a firm)
* economic "systems" (including "market"s and "economies") in "stable" equilibrium
* qualitative properties between two or more variables, such as an alleged technological relation or psychological law (indexed by the sign of the relevant functional relationship).Part I conjectures that meaningful theorems for economic units and for their respective aggregates are almost all derivable from general conditions of equilibrium. The equilibrium conditions can in turn be stated as "maximization conditions". So, meaningful theorems reduce to maximization conditions. The calculus of the relations is at a high level of abstraction but with the advantage of numerous applications. Finally, Part I illustrates that there "are" meaningful theorems in economics, which apply to diverse fields.

Part II concentrates on aggregation of economic units into equilibrium of the system. But the symmetry conditions required for direct maximization of the "system", whether a market or even the simplest model of the business cycle, are lacking, in contrast to an economic "unit" or its corresponding aggregate. What can be hypothetically derived (or rejected in some cases) is a "stable" equilibrium of the system. (This is an equilibrium of the system such that, if a variable disturbs equilibrium, the system converges to equilibrium.) "Stability of equilibrium" is proposed as the principal source of operationally meaningful theorems for economic systems (p. 5).

Analogies from physics (and biology) are conspicuous, such as the Le Chatelier principle and correspondence principle, but they are given a nontrivially generalized formulation and application. They and mathematical constructions, such as Lagrangean multipliers, are given an operational economic interpretation. The generalized "Le Chatelier principle" is for a maximum condition of equilibrium: where all unknowns of the function are independently variable, auxiliary constraints ("just-binding" in leaving initial equilibrium unchanged) reduce the response to a parameter change. Thus, factor-demand and commodity-supply elasticities are hypothesized to be lower in the short run than in the long run because of the fixed-cost constraint in the short run) (pp. 36, 38; Hatta, 1987, p. 155). In the course of analysis, "comparative statics", changes in equilibrium of the system that result from a parameter change of the system, is formalized and most clearly stated (Kehoe, 1987, p. 517). The "correspondence principle" is that the "stability" of equilibrium for a system (such as a market or economy) implies meaningful theorems in comparative statics. Alternatively, the hypothesis of stability imposes directional restrictions on the movement of the system (Samuelson, pp. 258, 5). The correspondence is between comparative statics and the dynamics implied by stability of equilibrium. The chapter on welfare economics is described as an attempt "to give a brief but fairly complete survey of the whole field of welfare economics" (p. 252). This Samuelson does in 51 pages, including his exposition of what became known as the Bergson-Samuelson social welfare function. Theorems derived in welfare economics, he notes, are deductive implications of assumptions that are not refutable, thus not meaningful in a certain sense. Still, the social welfare function can represent any index (cardinal or not) of the economic measures of any logically possible ethical belief system that is required to order any (hypothetically) feasible social configurations as "better than", "worse than", or "indifferent to" each other (p. 221). It also definitively elucidates (Fischer, 1987, p. 236) the notion of Pareto optimality and the "germ of truth in Adam Smith's doctrine of the Invisible Hand" (Samuelson, 1983, p. xxiv).

The final pages of the book (pp. 354-55) outline possible directions analytical methods might take, including for example models that show how:
* deficit financing could produce positive short-run effects on the economy that are swamped by adverse long-run effects on capital accumulation (seriously reconsidered later as crowding out)
* declines in age-specific mortality affect the net reproductive rate (whose the implications for population growth are [http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/
] than they might first appear).Samuelson closes by expressing hope in the future use of "comparative dynamics" to:: aid in the attack upon diverse problems -- from the trivial behavior of a single small commodity, to the fluctuations of important components of the business cycle, and even to the majestic problems of economic development.

Appendices

There are two mathematical appendices totalling 83 pages. The first gathers and develops "very briefly" and "without striving for rigor" results on maximization conditions and quadratic forms used in the book and not conveniently collected elsewhere (p. 389). The other is on difference equations ("for the dynamic economist") and other functional equations.

Enlarged edition

The 1983 Enlarged edition includes an additional 12-page "Introduction" and a new 145-page appendix with some post-1947 developments in analytical economics, including how conclusions of the book are affected by them.

Assessments

* Kenneth Arrow (1983, p. 19) describes "Foundations" as "the only example I know of a doctoral dissertation that is a treatise, perhaps I should say of a treatise that has so much originality in every part that it is entitled to be accepted as a thesis."
* Richard N. Cooper (1997) writes that the book "drastically redirected the advanced study of economics toward greater and more productive use of mathematics."
* Notwithstanding the important work of Arrow, Kotaro Suzumura (1987, p. 420) affirms the Bergson-Samuelson social welfare function as "logically impeccable."
* The Nobel Prize [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1970/index.html citation] is applicable to "Foundations": "for the scientific work through which [Samuelson] has developed static and dynamic economic theory and actively contributed to raising the level of analysis in economic science."

ee also

* Neoclassical economics
* Paul Samuelson
* Social welfare function

References

* Arrow, Kenneth J. (1983), "Contribution to Welfare Economics", E. Cary Brown and Robert M. Solow, ed., "Paul Samuelson and Modern Economic Theory", pp. 15-30.
* Boulding, Kenneth E. (1948). "Samuelson's Foundations: The Role of Mathematics in Economics," "Journal of Political Economy", 56(3), p [http://www.jstor.org/pss/1825768 p. 187] -199.
* Cooper, Richard N. (1997), [Book review] , [http://www.foreignaffairs.org/19970901fabook3617/paul-a-samuelson/economics-an-introductory-analysis.html] "Foreign Affairs", September/October
* Fischer, Stanley (1987), “Samuelson, Paul Anthony", "The ", v. 4, pp. 234-41.
* Hatta, Tatsuo (1987), "Le Chatelier principle", "The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics", v. 3, pp. 155-57.
* Kehoe, Timothy (1987), "Comparative statics", "The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics", v. 1, pp. 517-20.
* Metzler, Lloyd (1948), Review of "Foundations of Economic Analysis", in "American Economic Review" 38 (5), p [http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28194812%2938%3A5%3C905%3AFOEA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-0&size=LARGE&origin=JSTOR-enlargePage p. 905] -10.
* Samuelson, Paul A. (1947, Enlarged ed. 1983). "Foundations of Economic Analysis", Harvard University Press. ISBN 0-674-31301-1
* Stigler, George J. (1948). "Review," "Journal of the American Statistical Association", 43( 244), p [http://www.jstor.org/pss/2280713 p. 603] -605.
* Suzumura, Kotaro (1987), “social welfare function", "The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics", v. 4, pp. 418-20.

External links

* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1970/samuelson-lecture.html "Maximum Principles in Analytical Economics"] , link to Nobel Prize lecture
* [http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1970/press.html Nobel Prize presentation speech] , in which the first 3 areas discussed apply to "Foundations"


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать реферат

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Economic methodology — is the study of methods, usually scientific method, in relation to economics (Boland, 1987, p. 455). The term methodology is also commonly, though incorrectly, used as an impressive synonym for method or technique.Many of the general issues that… …   Wikipedia

  • Economic model — A diagram of the IS/LM model In economics, a model is a theoretical construct that represents economic processes by a set of variables and a set of logical and/or quantitative relationships between them. The economic model is a simplified… …   Wikipedia

  • Economic equilibrium — Price of market balance: P price Q quantity of good S supply D demand P0 price of market balance A surplus of demand when P<P0 B surplus of supply when P>P0 In economics, economic equilibrium is a state of the world where economic forces… …   Wikipedia

  • Economic Affairs — ▪ 2006 Introduction In 2005 rising U.S. deficits, tight monetary policies, and higher oil prices triggered by hurricane damage in the Gulf of Mexico were moderating influences on the world economy and on U.S. stock markets, but some other… …   Universalium

  • economic planning — Use of government to make economic decisions with respect to the use of resources. In communist countries with a state planning apparatus, detailed and rigid planning results in a command economy; land, capital, and the means of production are… …   Universalium

  • ECONOMIC HISTORY — This article is arranged according to the following outline: first temple period exile and restoration second temple period talmudic era muslim middle ages medieval christendom economic doctrines early modern period sephardim and ashkenazim… …   Encyclopedia of Judaism

  • Economic history of the United States — The economic history of the United States has its roots in European settlements in the 16th, 17th, and 18th centuries. The American colonies progressed from marginally successful colonial economies to a small, independent farming economy, which… …   Wikipedia

  • Economic impact of AIDS — [ legend line|red solid 2px|Botswanalegend line|darkgreen solid 2px|Zimbabwelegend line|blue solid 2px|Kenyalegend line|black solid 2px|South Africalegend line|grey solid 2px|Uganda] HIV and AIDS affects economic growth by reducing the… …   Wikipedia

  • History of economic thought — The history of economic thought deals with different thinkers and theories in the field of political economy and economics from the ancient world to the present day. British philosopher Adam Smith is cited by many as the father of modern… …   Wikipedia

  • Economic development — is the development of economic wealth of countries or regions for the well being of their inhabitants. From a policy perspective, economic development can be defined as efforts that seek to improve the economic well being and quality of life for… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”