- Vertical restraints
Vertical restraints are agreements between firms or individuals at different levels of the production and distribution process. Vertical restraints are to be distinguished from so-called “horizontal restraints,” which are agreements between horizontal competitors. Vertical restraints can take numerous forms, ranging from a requirement that dealers accept returns of a manufacturer’s product, to
resale price maintenance agreements setting the minimum or maximum price that dealers can charge for the manufacturer’s product.So-called “intrabrand restraints” such as resale price maintenance govern products made by a particular manufacturer, while “interbrand restraints” regulate a dealer’s or manufacturer’s relationship with its trading partner’s rivals. Quintessential examples of interbrand restraints include
tying contracts, whereby a purchaser agrees to purchase a second product as a condition of obtaining a so-called "tying" product, andexclusive dealing agreements, whereby a dealer agrees not to purchase products from suppliers that are rivals of the manufacturer.United States Anti-Trust Law
Section 1 of the
Sherman Antitrust Act governs all vertical restraints involving interstate commerce in the United States. Section 3 of the Clayton Act governs interbrand restraints involving the sale of “goods.” Finally, Section 2 of the Sherman Act governs restraints entered by monopolists. For several decades, courts were quite hostile to many vertical restraints, declaring them unlawful per se or nearly so. "See, e.g.," Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145 (1969) (declaring maximum resale price maintenance unlawful per se). More recently, courts have reversed course and held that most such restraints should be analyzed under the rule of reason. See Leegin Creative Leather Products v. PSKS, 127 S. Ct. 2705 (2007); Continental TV v. GTE Sylvania, 433 U.S. 36 (1978).
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.