- Bertrand paradox (economics)
:"For other paradoxes by Joseph Bertrand, see
Bertrand's paradox In economics and commerce, the Bertrand paradox– named after its creator,
Joseph Bertrand –describes a situation in which two players (firms) reach a state ofNash equilibrium .Suppose two firms, A and B, sell an identicalcommodity , each with the same cost of production and distribution, so that customers choose the product solely on the basis of price. It follows that neither A nor B will set a higher price than the other because doing so would yield the entire market to their rival. If they set the same price, the companies will share both the market and profits.On the other hand, if either firm were to lower its price, even a little, it would gain the whole market and substantially larger profits. Since both A and B know this, they will each try to undercut their competitor until the product is selling at zero economic profit. This is the pure-strategy
Nash equilibrium . Recent work has shown that there may be an additional mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium with positive economic profits (see Kaplan & Wettstein, 2000, and Baye & Morgan, 1999).The Bertrand paradox rarely appears in practice because real products are almost always differentiated in some way other than price (
brand name , if nothing else); firms have limitations on their capacity to manufacture and distribute; and two firms rarely have identical costs.Bertrand's result is paradoxical because if the number of firms goes from one to two, the price decreases from the
monopoly price to the competitive price and stays at the same level as the number of firms increases further. This is not very realistic, as in reality, the price goes down as the number of firms increases. The empirical analysis shows that in the most industries with two competitors, positive profits are made.Some reasons the Bertrand paradox does not strictly apply:
* "Capacity constraints"–Sometimes firms do not have enough capacity to satisfy all demand
* "Product differentiation"–If products of different firms are differentiated, then consumers may not switch completely to the product with lower price
* "Dynamic competition"–Repeated interaction or repeated price competition can lead to the price above MC in equilibrium.
* "More money for higher price"–It follows from repeated interaction: If one company sets their price slightly higher, then they will still get about the same amount of buys but more profit for each buy, so the other company will raise their price, and so on (only in repeated games, otherwise the price dynamics are in the other direction).
* "Oligopoly" If the two companies can agree on a price, it is in their long-term interest to keep the agreement: the revenue from cutting prices is less than twice the revenue from keeping the agreement, and lasts only until the other firm cuts its own prices.ee also
*
Joseph Bertrand
*Bertrand model
*Bertrand equilibrium
*Differentiated Bertrand competition
*Edgeworth paradox
*Efficient rationing
*Prisoner's dilemma References
* Baye, M.R. and J. Morgan (1997) "Necessary and sufficient conditions for existence and uniqueness of Bertrand paradox outcomes" Princeton Woodrow Wilson School, Discussion Paper in Economics, 186.
* Baye, M.R. and J. Morgan (1999) "A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games," Economics Letters, 65:1, 59-65.
* Bertrand, J. (1883) "Book review of theorie mathematique de la richesse sociale and of recherches sur les principles mathematiques de la theorie des richesses", Journal de Savants 67: 499–508.
* Kaplan, T.R. and D. Wettstein (1997) "Mixed strategy equilibria with constant-returns-to-scale technology," Monaster Center Discussion Paper 97–4.
* [http://www.springerlink.com/content/wuu31dtnc7d6rpty/ Kaplan, T.R. and D. Wettstein] , (2000) "The Possibility of Mixed-Strategy Equilibria with Constant-Returns-to-Scale Technology under Bertrand Competition", Spanish Economic Review, 2(1):65-71.
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.