- Coherent risk measure
-
In the field of financial economics there are a number of ways that risk can be defined; to clarify the concept theoreticians have described a number of properties that a risk measure might or might not have. A coherent risk measure is a function ρ that satisfies properties of monotonicity, sub-additivity, homogeneity, and translational invariance.
Contents
Properties
Consider a random outcome X viewed as an element of a linear space of measurable functions, defined on an appropriate probability space. A functional → is said to be coherent risk measure for if it satisfies the following properties:[1]
- Normalized
- ρ(0) = 0
That is, the risk of holding no assets is zero.
- Monotonicity
That is, if portfolio Z2 always has better values than portfolio Z1 under all scenarios then the risk of Z2 should be less than the risk of Z1.[2]
- Sub-additivity
Indeed, the risk of two portfolios together cannot get any worse than adding the two risks separately: this is the diversification principle.
- Positive homogeneity
Loosely speaking, if you double your portfolio then you double your risk.
- Translation invariance
The value a is just adding cash to your portfolio Z, which acts like an insurance: the risk of Z + a is less than the risk of Z, and the difference is exactly the added cash a. In particular, if a = ρ(Z) then ρ(Z + ρ(Z)) = 0.
Convex risk measures
The notion of coherence has been subsequently relaxed. Indeed, the notions of Sub-additivity and Positive Homogeneity can be replaced by the notion of convexity:[3]
- Convexity
Examples
Value at risk
It is well known that value at risk is not, in general, a coherent risk measure as it does not respect the sub-additivity property. An immediate consequence is that value at risk might discourage diversification.[citation needed]
Value at risk is, however, coherent, under the assumption of elliptically distributed losses (e.g. normally distributed) when the portfolio value is a linear function of the asset prices. However, in this case the value at risk becomes equivalent to a mean-variance approach where the risk of a portfolio is measured by the variance of the portfolio's return.
Illustration
As a simple example to demonstrate the non-coherence of value-at-risk consider looking at the VaR of a portfolio at 95% confidence over the next year of two default-able zero coupon bonds that mature in 1 years time denominated in our numeraire currency.
Assume the following:
- The current yield on the two bonds is 0%
- The two bonds are from different issuers
- Each bonds has a 4% probability of defaulting over the next year
- The event of default in either bond is independent of the other
- Upon default the bonds have a recovery rate of 30%
Under these conditions the 95% VaR for holding either of the bonds is 0% since the probability of default is less than 5%. However if we held a portfolio that consisted of 50% of each bond by value then the 95% VaR is 35% since the probability of at least one of the bonds defaulting is 7.84% which exceeds 5%. This violates the sub-additivity property showing that VaR is not a coherent risk measure.
Average value at risk
The average value at risk (sometimes called expected shortfall or conditional value-at-risk) is a coherent risk measure, even though it is derived from Value at Risk which is not.
Tail value at risk
The tail value at risk (or tail conditional expectation) is a coherent risk measure only when the underlying distribution is continuous.
Entropic risk measure
The entropic risk measure is a convex risk measure which is not coherent. It is related to the exponential utility.
Superhedging price
The superhedging price is a coherent risk measure.
Set-valued
In a situation with -valued portfolios such that risk can be measured in of the assets, then a set of portfolios is the proper way to depict risk. Set-valued risk measures are useful for markets with transaction costs.[4]
Properties
A set-valued coherent risk measure is a function , where and where K is a constant solvency cone and M is the set of portfolios of the m reference assets. R must have the following properties:[5]
- Normalized
- Translative in M
- Monotone
- Sublinear
Set-valued convex risk measure
If instead of the sublinear property,R is convex, then R is a set-valued convex risk measure.
Relation to Acceptance Sets
An acceptance set is convex (coherent) if and only if the corresponding risk measure is convex (coherent). As defined below it can be shown that and .
Risk Measure to Acceptance Set
- If ρ is a (scalar) risk measure then is an acceptance set.
- If R is a set-valued risk measure then is an acceptance set.
Acceptance Set to Risk Measure
- If A is an acceptance set (in 1-d) then defines a (scalar) risk measure.
- If A is an acceptance set then is a set-valued risk measure.
Dual representation
A convex risk measure ρ can be represented as
such that α is a penalty function.
A risk measure is coherent if and only if it can be represented as
such that .[6]
Relation to deviation risk measure
If for every X (where is the essential infimum) is a deviation risk measure, then there is a one-to-one relationship between D and an expectation-bounded coherent risk measure ρ where for any
- .
ρ is expectation bounded if for any nonconstant X and for any constant X.[7]
References
- ^ Artzner, Philippe; Delbaen, Freddy; Eber, Jean-Marc; Heath, David (1999). "Coherent Measures of Risk" (pdf). Mathematical Finance 9 (3): 203–228. http://www.math.ethz.ch/~delbaen/ftp/preprints/CoherentMF.pdf. Retrieved February 3, 2011.
- ^ Wilmott, P. (2006). Quantitative Finance. 1 (2 ed.). Wiley. p. 342.
- ^ Föllmer, H.; Schied, A. (2002). "Convex measures of risk and trading constraints". Finance and Stochastics 6 (4): 429–447.
- ^ Jouini, Elyes; Meddeb, Moncef; Touzi, Nizar (2004). "Vector–valued coherent risk measures". Finance and Stochastics 8 (4): 531–552.
- ^ Hamel, Andreas; Heyde, Frank (December 11, 2008) (pdf). Duality for Set-Valued Risk Measures. http://www.princeton.edu/~ahamel/SetRiskHamHey.pdf. Retrieved July 22, 2010.[dead link]
- ^ Föllmer, Hans; Schied, Alexander (2004). Stochastic finance: an introduction in discrete time (2 ed.). Walter de Gruyter. ISBN 9783110183467.
- ^ Rockafellar, Tyrrell; Uryasev, Stanislav; Zabarankin, Michael (2002) (pdf). Deviation Measures in Risk Analysis and Optimization. http://www.ise.ufl.edu/uryasev/Deviation_measures_wp.pdf. Retrieved October 13, 2011.}}
External links
- A list of important papers on coherent and convex risk measures
- Glyn Holton: The Case for Incoherence Controversial article that argues coherence is not a desirable property. "There are two types of risk metrics – coherent and incoherent. In the vast majority of cases, you want one that is incoherent."
See also
- RiskMetrics
- Spectral risk measure - a subset of coherent risk measures
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.