Largest remainder method

Largest remainder method

The largest remainder method is one way of allocating seats proportionally for representative assemblies with party list voting systems. It is a contrast to the highest averages method.

Quotas

There are several possibilities for the quota. The most common are: the Hare quota and the Droop quota.

The Hare (or simple) Quota is defined as follows

:frac{mbox{total} ; mbox{votes{mbox{total} ; mbox{seats

The Hamilton method of apportionment is actually a largest-remainder method which is specifically defined as using the Hare Quota, named after Alexander Hamilton, who invented the largest-remainder method, in 1792. It is used for legislative elections in Russia (with 7% exclusion threshold since 2007), Ukraine (3% threshold), Namibia and in the territory of Hong Kong. It was historically applied for congressional apportionment in the United States during the nineteenth century.

The Droop quota is the integer part of :1+frac{mbox{total} ; mbox{votes{1+mbox{total} ; mbox{seatsand is applied in elections in South Africa. The Hagenbach-Bischoff quota is similar, being :frac{mbox{total} ; mbox{votes{1+mbox{total} ; mbox{seatseither used as a fraction or rounded up.

The Hare quota tends to be slightly more generous to less popular parties and the Droop quota to more popular parties, in the extent in which it is arguably considered more proportional than Droop quota [http://www.parl.gc.ca/information/library/PRBpubs/bp334-e.htm] [http://polmeth.wustl.edu/polanalysis/vol/8/PA84-381-388.pdf] [http://www.dur.ac.uk/john.ashworth/EPCS/Papers/Suojanen.pdf] [http://users.ox.ac.uk/~sann2300/041102-ceg-electoral-consequences-lijphart.shtml] [http://janda.org/c24/Readings/Lijphart/Lijphart.html] although it is more likely to give fewer than half the seats to a list with more than half the vote.

The Imperiali quota :frac{mbox{total} ; mbox{votes{2+mbox{total} ; mbox{seatsis rarely used since it suffers from the problem that it may result in more candidates being elected than there are seats available (this can also occur with the Hagenbach-Bischoff quota but it's very unlikely and is impossible with the Hare and Droop quotas). This will certainly happen if there are only two parties. In such a case, it is usual to increase the quota until the number of candidates elected is equal to the number of seats available, in effect changing the voting system to the Jefferson apportionment formula (see D'Hondt method).

Examples

These examples take an election to allocate 10 seats where there are 100,000 votes.

Hare quota

Party Yellows Whites Reds Greens Blues Pinks Total
Votes 47,000 16,000 15,800 12,000 6,100 3,100 100,000
Seats 10
Hare Quota 10,000
Votes/Quota 4.70 1.60 1.58 1.20 0.61 0.31
Automatic seats 4 1 1 1 0 0 7
Remainder 0.70 0.60 0.58 0.20 0.61 0.31
Highest Remainder Seats 1 1 0 0 1 0 3
Total Seats 5 2 1 1 1 0 10

Droop quota

Party Yellows Whites Reds Greens Blues Pinks Total
Votes 47,000 16,000 15,800 12,000 6,100 3,100 100,000
Seats 10
Droop Quota 9,091
Votes/Quota 5.170 1.760 1.738 1.320 0.671 0.341
Automatic seats 5 1 1 1 0 0 8
Remainder 0.170 0.760 0.738 0.320 0.671 0.341
Highest Remainder Seats 0 1 1 0 0 0 2
Total Seats 5 2 2 1 0 0 10

Pros and cons

It is very easy for the average voter to understand how Largest Remainder allocates seats. Provided the Hare quota is used, it gives no advantage to lists with either a large or a small proportion of the votes - to that extent it is neutral. However, whether a list gets an extra seat or not is highly dependent on how the votes are distributed among other parties; it is quite possible for a party to make a slight percentage gain yet lose a seat. A related paradox is that increasing the number of seats may cause a party to lose a seat (the so-called Alabama paradox). The Sainte-Laguë method avoids these paradoxes but is less easy for the average voter to understand.

Technical evaluation and paradoxes

The largest remainder method is the only apportionment that satisfies the quota rule; in fact, it is designed to satisfy this criterion. However, it comes at the cost of paradoxical behaviour. The Alabama paradox is defined as when an increase in seats apportioned leads to decrease in the number of seats a certain party holds. Suppose we want to apportion 25 seats between 6 parties in the proportions 1500:1500:900:500:500:200. The two parties with 500 votes get three seats each. Now allocate 26 seats, and it will be found that the these parties get only two seats apiece.

With 25 seats, we get:

Party A B C D E F Total
Votes 1500 1500 900 500 500 200 5100
Seats 25
Hare Quota 204
Quotas Received 7.35 7.35 4.41 2.45 2.45 0.98
Automatic seats 7 7 4 2 2 0 22
Remainder 0.35 0.35 0.41 0.45 0.45 0.98
Surplus seats 0 0 0 1 1 1 3
Total Seats 7 7 4 3 3 1 25

With 26 seats, we have:

Party A B C D E F Total
Votes 1500 1500 900 500 500 200 5100
Seats 26
Hare Quota 196
Quotas Received 7.65 7.65 4.59 2.55 2.55 1.02
Automatic seats 7 7 4 2 2 1 23
Remainder 0.65 0.65 0.59 0.55 0.55 0.02
Surplus seats 1 1 1 0 0 0 3
Total Seats 8 8 5 2 2 1 26

ee also

* List of democracy and elections-related topics

External links

* [http://www.cut-the-knot.org/Curriculum/SocialScience/AHamilton.shtml Hamilton method experimentation applet] at cut-the-knot


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужен реферат?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • D'Hondt method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

  • Highest averages method — The highest averages method is one way of allocating seats proportionally for representative assemblies with party list voting systems. The highest averages method requires the number of votes for each party to be divided successively by a series …   Wikipedia

  • Sainte-Laguë method — The Sainte Laguë method of the highest average (equivalent to Webster s method or divisor method with standard rounding) is one way of allocating seats proportionally for representative assemblies with party list voting systems. It is named after …   Wikipedia

  • Kemeny–Young method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

  • Condorcet method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

  • Coombs' method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

  • Schulze method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

  • Copeland's method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

  • Nanson's method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

  • Dodgson's method — Part of the Politics series Electoral methods Single winner …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”