Bertil Ohlin

Bertil Ohlin

Infobox scientist
name = Bertil Ohlin


image_size = 180px
caption = Bertil Ohlin at Arosmässan in Västerås (late 1950s).
birth_date = birth date|1899|4|23
birth_place = Klippan, Sweden
death_date = death date and age|1979|8|3|1899|4|23
death_place = Valadalen, Sweden
field = Economics
work_institution = University of Copenhagen (1925–1930) Stockholm School of Economics (1930–1965)
alma_mater = B.A. Lund University (1917) M.A. Harvard University (1923) Ph.D. Stockholm University (1924)
doctoral_advisor = Gustav Cassel
doctoral_students =
known_for = Heckscher-Ohlin model Heckscher-Ohlin theorem
prizes = Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1977)

Bertil Gotthard Ohlin (pronounced|ˈbærtil uˈliːn) (23 April 18993 August 1979) was a Swedish economist and politician. He was a professor of economics at the Stockholm School of Economics from 1929 to 1965. He was also leader of the People's Party, a social-liberal party which at the time was the largest party in opposition to the governing Social Democratic Party, from 1944 to 1967. He served briefly as Minister for Trade from 1944 to 1945 in the Swedish coalition government during World War II.

Ohlin's name lives on in one of the standard mathematical model of international free trade, the Heckscher-Ohlin model, which he developed together with Eli Heckscher. He was jointly awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1977 together with the British economist James Meade "for their pathbreaking contribution to the theory of international trade and international capital movements".

Biography

Having received his B.A. from Lund University 1917, and his M.A. from Harvard University in 1923, Ohlin received his doctorate from Stockholm University in 1924. In 1925 he became a professor at the University of Copenhagen. In 1929 he debated with John Maynard Keynes, contradicting the latter's view on the consequences of the heavy war reparations payments imposed on Germany. (Keynes predicted a war caused by the burden of debt, Ohlin thought that Germany could afford the reparations.) Although Keynes was probably right, the debate was important in the modern theory of unilateral international payments.

In 1930 Ohlin succeeded Eli Heckscher, his teacher, as a professor of economics, at the Stockholm School of Economics. In 1933 Olin published a work that made him world renowned, "Interregional and International Trade". In this Ohlin built an economic theory of international trade from earlier work by Heckscher and his own doctoral thesis. It is now known as the Heckscher-Ohlin model, one of the standard model economists use to debate trade theory.

The model was a break-through because it showed how comparative advantage might relate to general features of a country's capital and labour, and how these features might change through time. The model provided a basis for later work on the effects of protection on real wages, and has been fruitful in producing predictions and analysis; Ohlin himself used the model to derive the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem, that nations would specialize in industries most able to utilize their mix of national resources efficiently. Today, the theory has been largely disproved, yet it is still a useful framework by which to understand international trade.

Later, Ohlin and other members of the "Stockholm school" extended Knut Wicksell's economic analysis to produce a theory of the macroeconomy anticipating Keynesianism.

Ohlin was party leader of the liberal Liberal People's Party from 1944 to 1967, the main opposition party to the Social Democrat Governments of the era, and from '44 to '45 was "minister of commerce" in the wartime government. His daughter Anne Wibble, representing the same party, served as Minister of Finance in 1991-1994.

Heckscher-Ohlin theorem

The Heckscher-Ohlin Theoem, which is concluded from the Heckscher-Ohlin model of international trade, states: trade between countries is in proportion to their relative amounts of capital and labor. In countries with an abundance of capital, wage rates tend to be high; therefore, labor-intensive products, e.g. textiles, simple electronics, etc., are more costly to produce internally. In contrast, capital-intensive products, e.g. automobiles, chemicals, etc., are relatively less costly to produce internally. Countries with large amounts of capital will export capital-intensive products and import labor-intensive products with the proceeds. Countries with high amounts of labor will do the reverse.

The following conditions must be true:
* The major factors of production, namely labor and capital, are not available in the same proportion in both countries.
* The two goods produced either require relatively more capital or relatively more labor.
* Labor and capital do not move between the two countries.
* There are no costs associated with transporting the goods between countries.
* The citizens of the two trading countries have the same needs.

The theory does not depend on total amounts of capital or labor, but on the amounts per worker. This allows small countries to trade with large countries by specializing in production of products that use the factors which are more available than its trading partner. The key assumption is that capital and labor are not available in the same proportions in the two countries. That leads to specialization, which in turn benefits the country’s economic welfare. The greater the difference between the two countries, the greater the gain from specialization.

Wassily Leontief made a study of the theory that seemed to invalidate it. He noted that the United States had a lot of capital; therefore, it should export capital-intensive products and import labor-intensive products. Instead, he found that it exported products that used more labor than the products it imported. This finding is known as the Leontief paradox.

See also

*Contributions to liberal theory
*Ohlin Report (1956)
*Faustman-Ohlin theorem

Significant Publications

* "The German Reparations Problem", 1930
* "Interregional and International Trade", 1933
* "Mechanisms and Objectives of Exchange Controls", 1937

Bibliography

* [http://www.britannica.com/ebc/article-61690 Encyclopedia Britannica Online "International trade"]
* [http://nobelprize.org/economics/educational/trade/ohlin.html NobelPrize.org "Why Trade?"]
* [http://www.internationalecon.com/v1.0/ch60/60c010.html Chapter 60 The Heckscher-Ohlin (Factor Proportions) Model]

Further reading

*cite book |author=John Cunningham Wood |title=Bertil Ohlin: Critical Assessments |publisher=Routledge |year=1995 |id=ISBN 978-0415074926

External links

* [http://www.nobel-winners.com/Economics/bertil_ohlin.html Bertil Ohlin]
* [http://www.ohlininstitutet.org/ Bertil Ohlin Institute]
* [http://www.economyprofessor.com/theorists/bertilohlin.php Ohlin's life in economics]
* [http://nobelprize.org/economics/laureates/1977/ohlin-autobio.html Bertil Ohlin – Autobiography]
* [http://nobelprize.org/economics/laureates/1977/ohlin-lecture.pdf Nobel lecture]
* [http://www.iies.su.se/publications/seminarpapers/684.pdf Presentation: THE YOUNG OHLIN ON THE THEORY OF INTERREGIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE]
* [http://ideas.repec.org/e/poh2.html IDEAS/RePEc]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем решить контрольную работу

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Bertil Ohlin — Bertil Ohlin. Bertil Ohlin (23 avril 1899 3 août 1979), est un économiste suédois. Son nom est attaché au modèle économique standard du libre échange international, le modèle Heckscher Ohlin Samuelson (HOS). En 1924, Ohlin reçoit son doctorat de… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Bertil Ohlin — Bertil Gotthard Ohlin (Aussprache: [ˌbæʁːtil ʊˈliːn], * 23. April 1899 in Klippan; † 3. August 1979 in Vålådalen, Gemeinde Åre) war ein schwedischer Ökonom und Politiker der …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Bertil Ohlin — Saltar a navegación, búsqueda Bertil Ohlin Bertil Ohlin (Klippan, Kristianstad, Suecia, 23 de abril de 1899 – Estocolmo, 3 de agosto de 1979), fue un un economista sueco, ganador del Premio No …   Wikipedia Español

  • Bertil Ohlin — A Swedish economist who received the 1977 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics, along with James Meade, for his research on international trade and international capital movements. Ohlin was born in 1899 in Sweden and died in 1979. He held a Ph.D.… …   Investment dictionary

  • Bertil Gotthard Ohlin — Bertil Ohlin Bertil Gotthard Ohlin (* 23. April 1899 in Klippan; † 3. August 1979 in Vålådalen, Gemeinde Åre) war ein schwedischer Ökonom und Politiker der Folkpartiet …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • OHLIN (B.) — OHLIN BERTIL (1899 1979) Professeur d’économie à l’université de Stockholm où il succède en 1930 à son maître Eli Heckscher, Bertil Ohlin est connu tout d’abord par ses contributions à l’analyse par périodes, d’une part, à l’étude des relations… …   Encyclopédie Universelle

  • Bertil — est un prénom masculin qui provient de l allemand « behrt » (brillant, illustre) et « til » (habile) et qui est commun en Suède et plus généralement en Scandinavie. Le féminin de ce nom est Bertille. Personnages historiques… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Bertil — ist ein schwedischer männlicher Vorname.[1] Inhaltsverzeichnis 1 Herkunft und Bedeutung 2 Bekannte Namensträger 3 Weblinks …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Ohlin — ist der Name folgender Personen: Bertil Ohlin (1899–1979), schwedischer Ökonom Lloyd E. Ohlin (1918–2008), US amerikanischer Soziologe und Kriminologe Sture Ohlin (* 1935), schwedischer Biathlet Per Yngve Ohlin, (1969 1991), schwedischer Musiker; …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Bertil — Infobox Given Name Revised name = Bertil imagesize= caption= pronunciation= gender = male meaning = region = origin = related names = footnotes = Bertil is a first name of German origin most commonly found among Swedish men. The oldest recorded… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”