- Capital asset pricing model
In
finance , the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) is used to determine a theoretically appropriate requiredrate of return of anasset , if that asset is to be added to an already well-diversified portfolio, given that asset's non-diversifiable risk. The model takes into account the asset's sensitivity to non-diversifiablerisk (also known assystemic risk ormarket risk ), often represented by the quantity beta (β) in the financial industry, as well as the expected return of the market and the expected return of a theoretical risk-free asset.The model was introduced by Jack Treynor, William Sharpe,
John Lintner andJan Mossin independently, building on the earlier work ofHarry Markowitz on diversification andmodern portfolio theory . Sharpe received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics (jointly with Markowitz andMerton Miller ) for this contribution to the field offinancial economics .The formula
The CAPM is a model for pricing an individual security or a portfolio. For individual securities, we made use of the
security market line (SML) and its relation to expected return and systematic risk (beta) to show how the market must price individual securities in relation to their security risk class. The SML enables us to calculate the reward-to-risk ratio for any security in relation to that of the overall market. Therefore, when the expected rate of return for any security is deflated by its beta coefficient, the reward-to-risk ratio for any individual security in the market is equal to the market reward-to-risk ratio, thus:,
The market reward-to-risk ratio is effectively the market risk premium and by rearranging the above equation and solving for E(Ri), we obtain the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM).
Where:
* is the expected return on the capital asset
* is the risk-free rate of interest
* (the "beta coefficient ") is thesensitivity of the asset returns to market returns, or also ,
* is the expected return of the market
* is sometimes known as the "market premium" or "risk premium" (the difference between the expected market rate of return and the risk-free rate of return). Note 1: the expected market rate of return is usually measured by looking at thearithmetic average of the historical returns on a market portfolio (i.e. S&P 500). Note 2: the risk free rate of return used for determining the risk premium is usually the arithmetic average of historical risk free rates of return and not the current risk free rate of return.For the full derivation see
Modern portfolio theory .Asset pricing
Once the expected return, , is calculated using CAPM, the future
cash flow s of the asset can bediscounted to theirpresent value using this rate (), to establish the correct price for the asset.In theory, therefore, an asset is correctly priced when its observed price is the same as its value calculated using the CAPM derived discount rate. If the observed price is higher than the valuation, then the asset is overvalued (and undervalued when the observed price is below the CAPM valuation).
Alternatively, one can "solve for the discount rate" for the observed price given a particular valuation model and compare that discount rate with the CAPM rate. If the discount rate in the model is lower than the CAPM rate then the asset is overvalued (and undervalued for a too high discount rate).
Asset-specific required return
The CAPM returns the asset-appropriate required return or discount rate - i.e. the rate at which future cash flows produced by the asset should be discounted given that asset's relative riskiness. Betas exceeding one signify more than average "riskiness"; betas below one indicate lower than average. Thus a more risky stock will have a higher beta and will be discounted at a higher rate; less sensitive stocks will have lower betas and be discounted at a lower rate. The CAPM is consistent with intuition - investors (should) require a higher return for holding a more risky asset.
Since beta reflects asset-specific sensitivity to non-diversifiable, i.e. market
risk , the market as a whole, by definition, has a beta of one. Stock market indices are frequently used as local proxies for the market - and in that case (by definition) have a beta of one. An investor in a large, diversified portfolio (such as amutual fund ) therefore expects performance in line with the market.Risk and diversification
The risk of a portfolio comprises
systematic risk , also known as undiversifiable risk, andunsystematic risk which is also known asidiosyncratic risk or diversifiable risk. Systematic risk refers to the risk common to all securities - i.e.market risk . Unsystematic risk is the risk associated with individual assets. Unsystematic risk can be diversified away to smaller levels by including a greater number of assets in the portfolio (specific risks "average out"). The same is not possible for systematic risk within one market. Depending on the market, a portfolio of approximately 30-40 securities in developed markets such as UK or US will render the portfolio sufficiently diversified to limit exposure to systemic risk only. In developing markets a larger number is required, due to the higher asset volatilities.A rational investor should not take on any diversifiable risk, as only non-diversifiable risks are rewarded within the scope of this model. Therefore, the required return on an asset, that is, the return that compensates for risk taken, must be linked to its riskiness in a portfolio context - i.e. its contribution to overall portfolio riskiness - as opposed to its "stand alone riskiness." In the CAPM context, portfolio risk is represented by higher
variance i.e. less predictability. In other words the beta of the portfolio is the defining factor in rewarding the systematic exposure taken by an investor.The efficient frontier
The CAPM assumes that the risk-return profile of a portfolio can be optimized - an optimal portfolio displays the lowest possible level of risk for its level of return. Additionally, since each additional asset introduced into a portfolio further diversifies the portfolio, the optimal portfolio must comprise every asset, (assuming no trading costs) with each asset value-weighted to achieve the above (assuming that any asset is infinitely divisible). All such optimal portfolios, i.e., one for each level of return, comprise the efficient frontier.
Because the unsystematic risk is diversifiable, the total risk of a portfolio can be viewed as beta.
The market portfolio
An investor might choose to invest a proportion of his or her wealth in a portfolio of risky assets with the remainder in cash - earning interest at the risk free rate (or indeed may borrow money to fund his or her purchase of risky assets in which case there is a negative cash weighting). Here, the ratio of risky assets to risk free asset does not determine overall return - this relationship is clearly linear. It is thus possible to achieve a particular return in one of two ways:
#By investing all of one's wealth in a risky portfolio,
#or by investing a proportion in a risky portfolio and the remainder in cash (either borrowed or invested).For a given level of return, however, only one of these portfolios will be optimal (in the sense of lowest risk). Since the risk free asset is, by definition, uncorrelated with any other asset, option 2 will generally have the lower variance and hence be the more efficient of the two.This relationship also holds for portfolios along the efficient frontier: a higher return portfolio plus cash is more efficient than a lower return portfolio alone for that lower level of return. For a given risk free rate, there is only one optimal portfolio which can be combined with cash to achieve the lowest level of risk for any possible return. This is the
market portfolio .Assumptions of CAPM
All Investors:
# Aim to maximize economic utility.
# Are rational risk-averse.
# Are price takers, i.e., they cannot influence prices.
# Can lend and borrow unlimited under the risk free rate of interest.
# Trade without transaction or taxation costs.
# Deal with securities that are all highly divisible into small parcels.Shortcomings of CAPM
*The model assumes that asset returns are (jointly) normally distributed
random variables. It is however frequently observed that returns in equity and other markets are not normally distributed. As a result, large swings (3 to 6 standard deviations from the mean) occur in the market more frequently than the normal distribution assumption would expect.
*The model assumes that the variance of returns is an adequate measurement of risk. This might be justified under the assumption of normally distributed returns, but for general return distributions other risk measures (likecoherent risk measure s) will likely reflect the investors' preferences more adequately.
*The model does not appear to adequately explain the variation in stock returns. Empirical studies show that low beta stocks may offer higher returns than the model would predict. Some data to this effect was presented as early as a 1969 conference inBuffalo, New York in a paper byFischer Black ,Michael Jensen , andMyron Scholes . Either that fact is itself rational (which saves theEfficient Market Hypothesis but makes CAPM wrong), or it is irrational (which saves CAPM, but makes the EMH wrong – indeed, this possibility makesvolatility arbitrage a strategy for reliably beating the market).
*The model assumes that given a certain expected return investors will prefer lower risk (lower variance) to higher risk and conversely given a certain level of risk will prefer higher returns to lower ones. It does not allow for investors who will accept lower returns for higher risk. Casino gamblers clearly pay for risk, and it is possible that some stock traders will pay for risk as well.
*The model assumes that all investors have access to the same information and agree about the risk and expected return of all assets (homogeneous expectations assumption).
*The model assumes that there are no taxes or transaction costs, although this assumption may be relaxed with more complicated versions of the model.
*The market portfolio consists of all assets in all markets, where each asset is weighted by its market capitalization. This assumes no preference between markets and assets for individual investors, and that investors choose assets solely as a function of their risk-return profile. It also assumes that all assets are infinitely divisible as to the amount which may be held or transacted.
*The market portfolio should in theory include all types of assets that are held by anyone as an investment (including works of art, real estate, human capital...) In practice, such a market portfolio is unobservable and people usually substitute a stock index as a proxy for the true market portfolio. Unfortunately, it has been shown that this substitution is not innocuous and can lead to false inferences as to the validity of the CAPM, and it has been said that due to the inobservability of the true market portfolio, the CAPM might not be empirically testable. This was presented in greater depth in a paper byRichard Roll in 1977, and is generally referred to asRoll's critique .See also
*Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)
*Efficient market hypothesis
*Hamada's Equation
*Modern portfolio theory
*Roll's critique
*ValuationReferences
*Black, Fischer., Michael C. Jensen, and Myron Scholes (1972). "The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Some Empirical Tests", pp. 79-121 in M. Jensen ed., Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets. New York: Praeger Publishers.
*Fama, Eugene F. (1968). "Risk, Return and Equilibrium: Some Clarifying Comments". Journal of Finance Vol. 23, No. 1, pp. 29-40.
*Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth French (1992). "The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns". Journal of Finance, June 1992, 427-466.
*French, Craig W. (2003). "The Treynor Capital Asset Pricing Model", Journal of Investment Management, Vol. 1, No. 2, pp. 60-72. Available at http://www.joim.com/
*French, Craig W. (2002). "Jack Treynor's 'Toward a Theory of Market Value of Risky Assets"' (December). Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=628187
*Lintner, John (1965). "The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets", Review of Economics and Statistics, 47 (1), 13-37.
*Markowitz, Harry M. (1999). "The early history of portfolio theory: 1600-1960", Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 55, No. 4
*Mehrling, Perry (2005). Fischer Black and the Revolutionary Idea of Finance. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
*Mossin, Jan. (1966). "Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market", Econometrica, Vol. 34, No. 4, pp. 768-783.
*Ross, Stephen A. (1977). "The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), Short-sale Restrictions and Related Issues", Journal of Finance, 32 (177)
*Rubinstein, Mark (2006). A History of the Theory of Investments. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
*Sharpe, William F. (1964). "Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk", Journal of Finance, 19 (3), 425-442
*Stone, Bernell K. (1970) Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: A General Single-Period Theory of Asset Selection and Capital-Market Equilibrium. Cambridge: MIT Press.
*Tobin, James (1958). "Liquidity preference as behavior towards risk", The Review of Economic Studies, 25
*Treynor, Jack L. (1961). "Market Value, Time, and Risk". Unpublished manuscript.
*Treynor, Jack L. (1962). "Toward a Theory of Market Value of Risky Assets". Unpublished manuscript. A final version was published in 1999, in Asset Pricing and Portfolio Performance: Models, Strategy and Performance Metrics. Robert A. Korajczyk (editor) London: Risk Books, pp. 15-22.
*Mullins, David W. (1982). "Does the capital asset pricing model work?", Harvard Business Review, January-February 1982, 105-113.External links
* [http://www.duke.edu/~charvey/twoasset/index.html two asset efficient frontier]
* [http://www.duke.edu/~charvey/frontier/frontier.html multiasset efficient frontier]
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.