Marginal revenue

Marginal revenue
Typical marginal revenue and average revenue (price) curves for a firm that is not in perfect competition

In microeconomics, marginal revenue (MR) is the extra revenue that an additional unit of product will bring. It is the additional income from selling one more unit of a good; sometimes equal to price.[1] It can also be described as the change in total revenue divided by the change in the number of units sold.

Contents

Definition

More formally, marginal revenue is equal to the change in total revenue over the change in quantity when the change in quantity is equal to one unit. This can also be represented as a derivative when the units of output are arbitrarily small. (Total revenue) = (Price that can be charged consistent with selling a given quantity) times (Quantity) or TR=P(Q) \cdot Q. Thus, by the product rule:

MR=\frac{dTR}{dQ}=\frac{dP}{dQ} \cdot Q + \frac{dQ}{dQ} \cdot P= Q \cdot \frac{dP}{dQ} + P.

For a firm facing perfectly competitive markets, price does not change with quantity sold (\frac{dP}{dQ}=0), so marginal revenue is equal to price. For a monopoly, the price received will decline with quantity sold (\frac{dP}{dQ}<0), so marginal revenue is less than price. This means that the profit-maximizing quantity, for which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost (MC) will be lower for a monopoly than for a competitive firm, while the profit-maximizing price will be higher. When demand is elastic, marginal revenue is positive, and when demand is inelastic, marginal revenue is negative. When the price elasticity of demand is equal to 1, marginal revenue is equal to zero.

Marginal revenue curve

The marginal revenue curve is affected by the same factors as the demand curve - changes in income, change in the prices of complements and substitutes, change in populations. These factors can cause the MR curve to shift and rotate.[2]

Relationship between marginal revenue and elasticity

The relationship between marginal revenue and the elasticity of demand by the firm's customers can be derived as follows:[3]

MR = dTR/dQ
MR = P+Q(dP/dQ)
MR = P[1 + (dP/dQ) (Q/P)]
MR = P(1 + 1/PED)

where PED is the price elasticity of demand. If demand is inelastic (PED < 1) then MR will be negative, because to sell a marginal (infinitesimal) unit the firm would have to lower the selling price so much that it would lose more revenue on the pre-existing units than it would gain on the incremental unit. If demand is elastic (PED > 1) MR will be positive, because the additional unit would not drive down the price by so much. If the firm is a perfect competitor, so that it is so small in the market that its quantity produced and sold has no effect on the price, then the price elasticity of demand is negative infinity, and marginal revenue simply equals the (market-determined) price.

Marginal revenue and rule of thumb pricing

Profit maximization requires that a firm produce where marginal revenue equals marginal costs. Firm managers are unlikely to have complete information concerning their marginal revenue function or their marginal costs. Fortunately the profit maximization conditions can be expressed in a “more easily applicable form” or rule of thumb.

MR = MC
MR = P(1 + 1/PED)
MC = P(1 + 1/PED)
MC = P + P/PED
(P - MC)/ P = - 1/PED[4]

Markup is the difference between price and marginal cost. The formula states that markup as a percentage of price equals the negative of the inverse of elasticity of demand.[5]Alternatively, the relationship can be expressed as:

P = MC/(1 + 1/PED)

Thus if PED is - 2 and MC is $5.00 then price is $10.00.

(P - MC)/ P = - 1/PED is called the Lerner index after economist Abba Lerner.[6] The Lerner index is a measure of market power - the ability of a firm to charge a price that exceeds marginal cost. The index varies from zero to 1. The greater the difference between price and marginal cost the closer the index value is to 1. The Lerner index increases as demand becomes less elastic.[6]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Sullivan & Sheffrin (2003), p. 112.
  2. ^ Landsburg, S Price 2002. p. 137.
  3. ^ Perloff (2008) p. 364.
  4. ^ Pindyck, R & Rubinfeld, D (2001) p. 334.
  5. ^ Pindyck, R & Rubinfeld, D (2001) p. 334.
  6. ^ a b Perloff (2008) p. 371.

References

  • Landsburg, S 2002 Price Theory & Applications, 5th ed. South-Western.
  • Perloff, J., 2008, Microeconomics: Theory & Applications with Calculus, Pearson. ISBN 978032127794
  • Pindyck, R & Rubinfeld, D 2001: Microeconomics 5th ed. Page Prentice-Hall. ISBN 0130196738
  • Samuelson & Marks, 2003 Managerial Economics 4th ed. Wiley
  • Sullivan, Arthur; Steven M. Sheffrin (2003). Economics: Principles in action. Pearson Prentice Hall. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.

Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем решить контрольную работу

Look at other dictionaries:

  • marginal revenue — marginal cost or marginal revenue noun (economics) The increase in a firm s total costs or revenue caused by producing one more unit of output • • • Main Entry: ↑margin …   Useful english dictionary

  • Marginal Revenue - MR — The increase in revenue that results from the sale of one additional unit of output. Marginal revenue is calculated by dividing the change in total revenue by the change in output quantity. While marginal revenue can remain constant over a… …   Investment dictionary

  • marginal revenue — The change in total revenue as a result of producing one additional unit of output. Bloomberg Financial Dictionary * * * marginal revenue marginal revenue ➔ revenue * * * marginal revenue UK US noun [C or U] ► ECONOMICS, ACCOUNTING the amount of… …   Financial and business terms

  • Marginal revenue productivity theory of wages — The marginal revenue productivity theory of wages, also referred to as the marginal revenue product of labor and the value of the marginal product or VMPL, is the change in total revenue earned by a firm that results from employing one more unit… …   Wikipedia

  • Marginal Revenue Product - MRP — The change in revenue that results from the addition of one extra unit when all other factors are kept equal. The marginal revenue product is used in marginal analysis to examine the effect of variable inputs, such as labor, and follows the law… …   Investment dictionary

  • marginal revenue — The additional revenue that a producer will achieve by selling one additional unit of production …   Big dictionary of business and management

  • Marginal Revenue — ⇡ Deckungsbeitrag …   Lexikon der Economics

  • marginal revenue — income of a business from sales of every additional product, MR (Economics) …   English contemporary dictionary

  • marginal revenue — The additional income that accrues to an organization as the result of selling an extra unit of sales …   Accounting dictionary

  • marginal revenue — /ˌmɑ:dʒɪn(ə)l revenju:/ noun the income from selling a single extra unit above the number already sold …   Marketing dictionary in english

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”