Joseph Tainter

Joseph Tainter

Joseph A. Tainter (Born December 8, 1949) is a U.S. anthropologist and historian.

Tainter studied anthropology at the University of California and Northwestern University, where he received his Ph.D. in 1975.[1] He is currently a professor in the Department of Environment and Society at Utah State University. His previous positions include Project Leader of Cultural Heritage Research, Rocky Mountain Forest and Range Experiment Station, Albuquerque, New Mexico and professor of anthropology at the University of New Mexico. Tainter is the author or editor of many articles and monographs. His best-known work is The Collapse of Complex Societies (1988), which examines the collapse of Maya and Chacoan civilizations,[2] and the Roman Empire, in terms of network theory, energy economics and complexity theory. Tainter argues that sustainability or collapse of societies follow from the success or failure of problem-solving institutions[3] and that societies collapse when their investments in social complexity and their "energy subsidies" reach a point of diminishing marginal returns. He recognizes collapse when a society rapidly sheds a significant portion of its complexity.

Contents

Social complexity

According to Tainter's Collapse of Complex Societies, societies become more complex as they try to solve problems. Social complexity can be recognized by numerous differentiated and specialised social and economic roles and many mechanisms through which they are coordinated, and by reliance on symbolic and abstract communication, and the existence of a class of information producers and analysts who are not involved in primary resource production. Such complexity requires a substantial "energy" subsidy (meaning the consumption of resources, or other forms of wealth). When a society confronts a "problem," such as a shortage of energy, or difficulty in gaining access to it, it tends to create new layers of bureaucracy, infrastructure, or social class to address the challenge. Tainter, who first (ch. 1) identifies seventeen examples of rapid collapse of societies, applies his model to three case studies: The Western Roman Empire, the Maya civilization, and the Chaco culture.

For example, as Roman agricultural output slowly declined and population increased, per-capita energy availability dropped. The Romans "solved" this problem by conquering their neighbours to appropriate their energy surpluses (in concrete forms, as metals, grain, slaves, etc.). However, as the Empire grew, the cost of maintaining communications, garrisons, civil government, etc. grew with it. Eventually, this cost grew so great that any new challenges such as invasions and crop failures could not be solved by the acquisition of more territory. Intense, authoritarian efforts to maintain cohesion by Domitian and Constantine the Great only led to an ever greater strain on the population. The empire was split into two halves, of which the western soon fragmented into smaller units. The eastern half, being wealthier, was able to survive longer, and did not collapse but instead succumbed slowly and piecemeal, because unlike the western empire it had powerful neighbors able to take advantage of its weakness.

We often assume that the collapse of the western Roman Empire was a catastrophe for everyone involved. Tainter points out that it can be seen as a very rational preference of individuals at the time, many of whom were actually better off. Archeological evidence from human bones indicates that average nutrition actually improved after the collapse in many parts of the former Roman Empire. Average individuals may have benefited because they no longer had to invest in the burdensome complexity of empire. Tainter notes that in the west, local populations in many cases greeted the barbarians as liberators.

Diminishing returns

Tainter begins by categorizing and examining the often inconsistent explanations that have been offered for collapse in the literature.[4] In Tainter's view, while invasions, crop failures, disease or environmental degradation may be the apparent causes of societal collapse, the ultimate cause is an economic one, inherent in the structure of society rather than in external shocks which may batter them: diminishing returns on investments in social complexity. For contrast, Jared Diamond's 2005 book, Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed, focuses on environmental mismanagement as a cause of collapse. Finally, Tainter musters modern statistics to show that marginal returns on investments in energy, education and technological innovation are diminishing today. The globalised modern world is subject to many of the same stresses that brought older societies to ruin.[5]

However, Tainter is not entirely apocalyptic: "When some new input to an economic system is brought on line, whether a technical innovation or an energy subsidy, it will often have the potential at least temporarily to raise marginal productivity" (p. 124). Thus, barring continual conquest of your neighbors (which is always subject to diminishing returns), innovation that increases productivity is – in the long run – the only way out of the dismal science dilemma of declining marginal returns on added investments in complexity. And in his final chapters, Tainter discusses why modern societies may not be able to choose to collapse: because surrounding them are other complex societies which will in some way absorb a collapsed region or prevent a general collapse; the Mayan and Chaocan regions had no powerful complex neighbors and so could collapse for centuries or millennia, as could the Western Roman Empire - but the Eastern Roman Empire, bordered as it was by the Parthian/Sassanid Empire, did not have the option of devolving into simpler smaller entities.

His paper Complexity, Problem Solving, and Sustainable Societies (1996) focuses on the energy cost of problem solving, and the energy-complexity relation in manmade systems.

Notes

  1. ^ Tainter's cuuriculum vitae at Sustainability International website; [http://www.cnr.usu.edu/htm/facstaff/memberID=837 Utah State University: Dr Tainter's homepage: accessed 30 August 2010.
  2. ^ He brought together a multidisciplinary group to examine the Chaco culture in Evolving Complexity and Environmental Risk in the Prehistoric Southwest (Santa Fe Institute Proceedings 24), edited with Bonnie Bagley Tainter, 1998.
  3. ^ Tainter, Joseph A (September 2000), "Problem Solving: Complexity, History, Sustainability", Population & Environment 22 (1): 3-41, http://www.fraw.org.uk/files/economics/tainter_2000.pdf, retrieved 11 October 2011 
  4. ^ "In the collapse of states Tainter has found a big gap in the literature," observed E. L. Jones, reviewing The Collapse of Complex Societies in The Economic History Review n.s. 42.4 (November 1989:634)
  5. ^ This aspect was criticized as "unconvincingly dire glosses on production costs in the world today" (E. L. Jones in The Economic History Review, New Series, 42.4 (November 1989:634).

See also

Leopold Kohr, The Breakdown of Nations, 1957

References

External links


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем сделать НИР

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Joseph Tainter — (né le 8 décembre 1949) est un anthropologue et un historien américain. Joseph Tainter a étudié l’anthropologie à l’université de Californie et à la Northwestern University, où il a reçu son Ph.D. en 1975[1]. Il est actuellement professeur dans… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Tainter — can refer to:People* Charles Sumner Tainter, engineer and inventor * Jeremiah Burnham Tainter, engineer * Joseph Tainter, anthropologist and historianPlaces* Tainter, WisconsinOther* Tainter gate on a dam …   Wikipedia

  • Economía energética — Saltar a navegación, búsqueda Consumo de electricidad por países La economía energética es una subclase de la economía que se centra en sus relaciones con la energía (tecnología) como base de todas las demás relaciones. Es una subclase de la …   Wikipedia Español

  • Societal collapse — broadly includes both quite abrupt societal failures typified by collapses (such as that of the Mayan Civilization), as well as more extended gradual declines of superpowers (like the Roman empire in Western Europe and the Han Dynasty in East… …   Wikipedia

  • Decline of the Roman Empire — This article is about the historiography of the decline of the Roman Empire. For a description of events, see Roman Empire. For the book by Edward Gibbon, see The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire. For the film, see The Fall of… …   Wikipedia

  • Colapso societal — Restos de los Colosos de Memnón, Tebas (Egipto) El colapso social, colapso societal o catástrofe social es una quiebra a gran escala o una declinación a largo plazo de la cultura, las instituciones civiles o de otras características principales… …   Wikipedia Español

  • Complexity, Problem Solving, and Sustainable Societies — is a paper on energy economics by Joseph Tainter from 1996. Contents 1 Focus 1.1 Attempts 1.2 Requirement of knowledge 2 See …   Wikipedia

  • Effondrement. Comment les sociétés décident de leur disparition ou de leur survie — Effondrement (livre) Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed est un livre écrit en 2005 par Jared Diamond, et traduit en 2006 sous le titre Effondrement. Comment les sociétés décident de leur disparition ou de leur survie. Le sujet du… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Effondrement (Livre) — Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed est un livre écrit en 2005 par Jared Diamond, et traduit en 2006 sous le titre Effondrement. Comment les sociétés décident de leur disparition ou de leur survie. Le sujet du livre est l… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Effrondrement — Effondrement (livre) Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed est un livre écrit en 2005 par Jared Diamond, et traduit en 2006 sous le titre Effondrement. Comment les sociétés décident de leur disparition ou de leur survie. Le sujet du… …   Wikipédia en Français

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”