- Post-modern portfolio theory
Post-modern portfolio theory [The earliest citation of the term 'Post-Modern Portfolio Theory' in the literature appears in 1993 in the article "Post-Modern Portfolio Theory Comes of Age" by Brian M. Rom and Kathleen W. Ferguson, published in The Journal of Investing, Winter, 1993. Summarized versions of this article have been subsequently published in a number of other journals and websites.] (or "PMPT") is an extension of the traditional
modern portfolio theory (“MPT”, also referred to as Mean-Variance Analysis or “MVA”). Both theories propose how rational investors should use diversification to optimize their portfolios, and how a risky asset should be priced.Overview
Harry Markowitz laid the foundations of MPT, the greatest contribution of which is the establishment of a formal risk/return framework for investment decision-making. By defining investment risk in quantitative terms, Markowitz gave investors a mathematical approach to asset-selection and portfolio management. But there are important limitations to the original MPT formulation.The limitations of MPT are the assumptions that 1) variance [In MPT, the terms variance, variability, volatility and standard deviation are used interchangeably to represent investment risk.] of portfolio returns is the correct measure of investment risk, and 2) the investment returns of all securities and portfolios can be adequately represented by the normal distribution. Stated another way, MPT is limited by measures of risk and return that do not always represent the realities of the investment markets.
Standard deviation and the normal distribution are a major practical limitation: they are symmetrical. Using standard deviation implies that better-than-expected returns are just as risky as those returns that are worse than expected. Furthermore, using the normal distribution to model the pattern of investment returns makes investment results with more upside than downside returns appear more risky than they really are, and vice-versa for returns with more a predominance of downside returns. The result is that using traditional MPT techniques for measuring investment portfolio construction and evaluation frequently distorts investment reality.
It has long been recognized that investors typically do not view as risky those returns "above" the minimum they must earn in order to achieve their investment objectives. They believe that risk has to do with the bad outcomes (i.e., returns below a required target), not the good outcomes (i.e., returns in excess of the target) and that losses weigh more heavily than gains. This view has been noted by researchers in finance, economics and psychology, including Sharpe (1964). "Under certain conditions the MVA can be shown to lead to unsatisfactory predictions of (investor) behavior. Markowitz suggests that a model based on the semivariance would be preferable; in light of the formidable computational problems, however, he bases his (MV) analysis on the mean and the standard deviation [See Sharpe [1964] . Markowitz recognized these limitations and proposed downside risk (which he called "semivariance") as the preferred measure of investment risk. The complex calculations and the limited computational resources at his disposal, however, made practical implemetations of downside risk impossible. He therefore compromised and stayed with variance.] ."
Recent advances in portfolio and financial theory, coupled with today’s increased electronic computing power, have overcome these limitations. The resulting expanded risk/return paradigm is known as Post-Modern Portfolio Theory, or PMPT. Thus, MPT becomes nothing more than a (symmetrical) special case of PMPT.
The Tools of PMPT
In 1987 The Pension Research Institute at San Francisco State University developed the practical mathematical algorithms of PMPT that are in use today. These methods provide a framework that recognizes investors' preferences for upside over downside volatility. At the same time, a more robust model for the pattern of investment returns, the three-parameter lognormal distribution [The three-parameter lognormal distribution is the only pdf that has thus far been developed for robust solutions of downside risk calculations permits both positive and negative skewness in return distributions. This is a more robust measure of portfolio returns than the normal distribution, which requires that the upsides and downside tails of the distribution be identical.] , was introduced.
Downside risk
Downside risk (DR) is measured by target semi-deviation (the square root of target semivariance) and is termed downside deviation. It is expressed in percentages and therefore allows for rankings in the same way as
standard deviation .An intuitive way to view downside risk is the annualized standard deviation of returns below the target. Another is the square root of the probability-weighted squared below-target returns. The squaring of the below-target returns has the effect of penalizing failures at an exponential rate. This is consistent with observations made on the behavior of individual decision-making under
:
where
"d" is downside deviation (commonly known in the financial community as 'downside risk'). Note: By extension, "d"² = downside variance.
"t" is the annual target return, originally termed the minimum acceptable return, or MAR.
"r" is the random variable representing the return for the distribution of annual returns "f"("r"),
"f"("r") is the three-parameter
lognormal distribution For the reasons provided below, this "continuous" formula is preferred over a simpler "discrete" version that determines the standard deviation of below-target periodic returns taken from the return series.
1. The continuous form permits all subsequent calculations to be made using annual returns which is the natural way for investors to specify their investment goals. The discrete form requires monthly returns for there to be sufficient data points to make a meaningful calculation, which in turn requires converting the annual target into a monthly target. This significantly affects the amount of risk that is identified. For example, a goal of earning 1% in every month of one year results in a greater risk than the seemingly equivalent goal of earning 12% in one year.
2. A second reason for strongly preferring the continuous form to the discrete form has been proposed by Sortino & Forsey (1996): "Before we make an investment, we don't know what the outcome will be... After the investment is made, and we want to measure its performance, all we know is what the outcome was, not what it could have been. To cope with this uncertainty, we assume that a reasonable estimate of the range of possible returns, as well as the probabilities associated with estimation of those returns...In statistical terms, the shape of [this] uncertainty is called a probability distribution. In other words, looking at just the discrete monthly or annual values does not tell the whole story."
Using the observed points to create a distribution is a staple of conventional performance measurement. For example, monthly returns are used to calculate a fund's mean and standard deviation. Using these values and the properties of the normal distribution, we can make statements such as the likelihood of losing money (even though no negative returns may actually have been observed), or the range within which two-thirds of all returns lies (even though the specific returns identifying this range have not necessarily occurred). Our ability to make these statements comes from the process of assuming the continuous form of the normal distribution and certain of its well-known properties.
In PMPT an analogous process is followed: 1. Observe the monthly returns, 2. Fit a distribution that permits asymmetry to the observations, 3. Annualize the monthly returns, making sure the shape characteristics of the distribution are retained, 4. Apply integral calculus to the resultant distribution to calculate the appropriate statistics.
ortino ratio
The
Sortino ratio measures returns adjusted for the target and downside risk. It is defined as::
where,
"r" = the annualized rate of return,
"t" = the target return,
"d" = downside risk.
The following table shows that this ratio is demonstrably superior to the traditional
Sharpe ratio as a means for ranking investment results. The table shows risk-adjusted ratios for several major indexes using both Sortino and Sharpe ratios. The data cover the five years 1992-1996 and are based on monthly total returns. The Sortino ratio is calculated against a 9.0% target.As an example of the different conclusions that can be drawn using these two ratios, notice how the Lehman Aggregate and MSCI EAFE compare - the Lehman ranks higher using the Sharpe ratio whereas EAFE ranks higher using the Sortino ratio. In many cases, manager or index rankings will be different, depending on the risk-adjusted measure used. These patterns will change again for different values of t. For example, when t is close to the risk-free rate, the Sortino Ratio for T-Bill's will be higher than that for the S&P 500, while the Sharpe ratio remains unchanged.
In March, 2008 researchers at the Queensland, Australia Investment Corporation showed that for skewed return distributions, the Sortino ratio is superior to the Sharpe ratio as a measure of portfolio risk. [http://www.agsm.edu.au/eajm/0803/Paper_5_Chaudhry_Johnson.html]
Volatility skewness
Volatility skewness is another portfolio-analysis statistic introduced by Rom and Ferguson under the PMPT rubric. It measures the ratio of a distribution's percentage of total variance from returns above the mean, to the percentage of the distribution's total variance from returns below the mean. Thus, if a distribution is symmetrical (i.e., normal, as is assumed under MPT), it has a volatility skewness of 1.00. Values greater than 1.00 indicate positive skewness; values less than 1.00 indicate negative skewness. While closely correlated with the traditional statistical measure of skewness (viz., the third moment of a distribution), the authors of PMPT argue that their volatility skewness measure has the advantage of being intuitively more understandable to non-statisticians who are the primary practical users of these tools.
The importance of skewness lies in the fact that the more non-normal (i.e., skewed) a return series is, the more its true risk will be distorted by traditional MPT measures such as the Sharpe ratio. Thus, with the recent advent of hedging and derivative strategies, which are asymmetrical by design, MPT measures are essentially useless, while PMPT is able to capture significantly more of the true information contained in the returns under consideration. This being said, as the following table shows, many of the common market indices and the returns of stock and bond mutual funds cannot themselves always be assumed to be accurately represented by the normal distribution. This fact is also not well understood by many practitioners.
Data: Monthly returns, January, 1991 through December, 1996.
Endnotes
References
*For a comprehensive survey of the early literature, see R. Libby and P. Fishburn [1979] .
*Bawa, V.S. "Stochastic Dominance: A Research Bibliography." Management Science, June, 1982.
*Balzer, L.A. "Measuring Investment Risk: A Review." The Journal of Investing, Fall 1994.
*Clarkson, R.S. Presentation to the Faculty of Actuaries (British).february 20 1989 .
*Fishburn, P.C. "Mean-Risk Analysis with Risk Associated with Below-Target Returns." American Economic Review, March 1977.
*Hammond, D.R. "Risk Management Approaches in Endowment Portfolios in the 1990's" Journal of Investing, Summer, 1993.
*Harlow, W.V. "Asset Allocation in a Downside Risk Framework." Financial Analysts Journal, Sept-Oct 1991.
*"Investment Review." Brinson Partners, Inc. 1992.
*Kaplan, P. and L. Siegel. "Portfolio Theory is Alive and Well," Journal of Investing, Fall 1994.
*Lewis, A.L. "Semivariance and the Performance of Portfolios with Options." Financial Analysts Journal, July-August 1990.
*Leibowitz, M.L. and S. Kogelman. "Asset Allocation under Shortfall Constraints." Salomon Brothers, 1987.
*Leibowitz, M.L., and T.C. Langeteig. "Shortfall Risks and the Asset Allocation Decision." Journal of Portfolio management, Fall 1989.
*Libby, R. and P. Fishburn. "Behavioral Models of Risk taking in Business decisions: A Survey and Evaluation," Journal of Accounting Research, Autumn 1977. See also D. Kahneman and A. Tversky, "Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk," Econometrica, March 1979.
*Post-Modern Portfolio Theory Spawns Post-Modern Optimizer." Money Management Letter,February 15 1993 .
*Rom, B. M. and K. Ferguson. "Post-Modern Portfolio Theory Comes of Age." Journal of Investing, Winter 1993.
*Rom, B. M. and K. Ferguson. "Portfolio Theory is Alive and Well: A Response." Journal of Investing, Fall 1994.
*Rom, B. M. and K. Ferguson. "A software developer's view: using Post-Modern Portfolio Theory to improve investment performance measurement." Managing downside risk in financial markets: Theory, practice and implementation; Butterworth-Heinemann Finance, 2001; p59.
*Sharpe, W.F. "Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Consideration of Risk." Journal of Finance, Vol. XIX (1964)
*Sortino, F. "Looking only at return is risky, obscuring real goal." Pensions and Investments magazine,November 25 1997 .
*Sortino, F. and H. Forsey "On the Use and Misuse of Downside Risk." The Journal of Portfolio Management, Winter 1996.
*Sortino, F. and L. Price. "Performance Measurement in a Downside Risk Framework." Journal of Investing, Fall 1994.
*Sortino, F. and S. Satchell, editors. "Managing downside risk in financial markets: Theory, practice and implementation" Butterworth-Heinemann Finance, 2001.
*Sortino, F. and R. van der Meer. "Downside Risk: Capturing What's at Stake." Journal of Portfolio Management, Summer 1991.
*"Why Investors Make the Wrong Choices." Fortune Magazine, January 1987.External links
*http://investmenttechnologies.com/publications.html
*http://www.fpanet.org/journal/articles/2005_Issues/jfp0905-art7.cfm
*http://www.bwater.com/Uploads/FileManager/In_the_News/engineering_targeted_returns_and_risks_pmpt_060215.pdf
*http://investmenttechnologies.com/about.html
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.