Hyperbolic discounting

Hyperbolic discounting

In behavioral economics, hyperbolic discounting refers to the empirical finding that people generally prefer smaller, sooner payoffs to larger, later payoffs when the smaller payoffs would be imminent; but when the same payoffs are distant in time, people tend to prefer the larger, even though the time lag from the smaller to the larger would be the same as before.

History

The phenomenon of hyperbolic discounting is implicit in Richard Herrnstein's "matching law," the discovery that most subjects allocate their time or effort between two non-exclusive, ongoing sources of reward (concurrent variable interval schedules) in direct proportion to the rate and size of rewards from the two sources, and in inverse proportion to their delays. That is, subjects' choices "match" these parameters.

After the report of this effect in the case of delay (Chung and Herrnstein, 1967), George Ainslie pointed out that in a single choice between a larger, later and a smaller, sooner reward, inverse proportionality to delay would be described by a plot of value by delay that had a hyperbolic shape, and that this shape should produce a reversal of preference from the larger, later to the smaller, sooner reward for no other reason but that the delays to the two rewards got shorter. He demonstrated the predicted reversal in pigeons (Ainslie, 1974).

A large number of subsequent experiments have confirmed that spontaneous preferences by both human and nonhuman subjects follow a hyperbolic curve rather than the conventional, "exponential" curve that would produce consistent choice over time (Green et.al., 1994; Kirby, 1997). For instance, when offered the choice between $50 now and $100 a year from now, many people will choose the immediate $50. However, given the choice between $50 in five years or $100 in six years almost everyone will choose $100 in six years, even though that is the same choice seen at five years' greater distance.

Notice that whether discounting future gains is logically correct or not, and at what rate such gains should be discounted, depends greatly on circumstances. Many examples exist in the financial world, for example, where it is logically reasonable to assume that there is an implicit risk that the reward will not be available at the future date, and furthermore that this risk increases with time. Consider: Paying $50 for your dinner today or delaying payment for sixty years but paying $100,000. In this case the restaurateur would be reasonable to discount the promised future value as there is significant risk that it might not be paid (possibly due to your death, his death, etc).

In cases where both alternatives are fairly certain to occur if chosen this pattern of discounting is dynamically inconsistent, and therefore inconsistent with standard models of rational choice, since the rate of discount between time "t" and "t+1" will be low at time "t-1", when "t" is the near future, but high at time "t" when "t" is the present and time "t+1" the near future. Nevertheless, it appears to be descriptively accurate.

Applications

More recently these observations about discount functions have been used to study saving for retirement, borrowing on credit cards, and procrastination. However, hyperbolic discounting has been most frequently used to explain addiction.

Hyperbolic discounting has been found to relate to real-world examples of self control. Indeed, a variety of studies have used measures of hyperbolic discounting to find that drug dependent individuals discount delayed consequences more than matched nondependent controls, suggesting that extreme delay discounting is a fundamental behavioral process in drug dependence (e.g., Bickel & Johnson, 2003; Madden et al., 1997; Vuchinich & Simpson, 1998). Some evidence suggests pathological gamblers also discount delayed outcomes at higher rates than matched controls (e.g., Petry & Casarella, 1999). Whether high rates of hyperbolic discounting precede addictions or vice-versa is currently unknown, although some studies have reported that high-rate discounting rats are more likely to consume alcohol (e.g., Poulos et al., 1995) and cocaine (Perry et al., 2005) than lower-rate discounters. Likewise, some have suggested that high-rate hyperbolic discounting makes unpredictable (gambling) outcomes more satisfying (Madden et al., 2007).

Mathematical model

The functional equation for hyperbolic discounting is as follows:

f(D)=frac{1}{1+kD}

where f(D) is the discount factor that multiplies the value of the reward, D is the delay in the reward, and k is a parameter governing the degree of discounting.

The degree of discounting is vitally important in describing hyperbolic discounting, especially in the discounting of specific rewards such as money. The discounting of monetary rewards varies across age groups due to the varying rate of k (Green, Frye, and Myerson, 1994). k depends on a variety of factors, including the species being observed, age, experience, and the amount of time needed to consume the reward (Lowenstein and Prelec, 1992; Raineri and Rachlin, 1993).

Quasi-hyperbolic approximation

The "quasi-hyperbolic" discount function, which approximates the hyperbolic discount function above, is given (in discrete time) by

f(0)=1, andf(D)=eta * delta^D,

where eta and delta are constants between 0 and 1; and again D is the delay in the reward, and f(D) is the discount factor. The condition f(0)=1 is stating that rewards taken at the present time are not discounted.

Quasi-hyperbolic time preferences are also referred to as "present-biased" or "beta-delta" preferences. They retain much of the analytical tractability of exponential discounting while capturing the key qualitative feature of discounting with true hyperbolas.

While originally introduced only as an approximation of hyperbolic discounting, there is now some evidence from neurophysiology that it is in fact a more accurate model of human behavior. [S. McClure et al., "Separate neural systems evaluate immediate and delayed monetary rewards," "Science" 306 (2004), 503-7, cited in Jon Elster, "Explaining Social Behavior", 118 and 123]

ee also

* Time value of money
* Time preference
* Intertemporal choice
* deferred gratification

References

Footnotes

General references

* Ainslie, G. W. (1974) Impulse control in pigeons. "Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior" 21,485-489.
* Ainslie, G. W. (1975) Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulsive control. "Psychological Bulletin", 82, 463-496.
* Ainslie, G. (1992) "Picoeconomics: The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States Within the Person". Cambridge. Cambridge University Press.
* Ainslie, G. (2001) "Breakdown of Will" Cambridge, Cambridge University Press
* Bickel, W. K., & Johnson, M. W. (2003). Delay discounting: A fundamental behavioral process of drug dependence. In G. Loewenstein, D. Read & R. F. Baumeister (Eds.), Time and Decision. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
* Chung, S. H. and Herrnstein, R. J. (1967). Choice and delay of Reinforcement. "Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 10" 67-64.
* Green, L., Fry, A. F., and Myerson, J. (1994). Discounting of delayed rewards: A life span comparison. "Psychological Science, 5", 33-36.
* Kirby, K. N. (1997) Bidding on the future: Evidence against normative discounting of delayed rewards. "Journal of Experimental Psychology: General" 126, 54-70.
* Loewenstein, G. and Prelec, D. (1992). "Choices Over Time" New York, Russell Sage Foundation
* Madden, G. J., Petry, N. M., Bickel, W. K., and Badger, G. J. (1997). Impulsive and self-control choices in opiate-dependent patients and non-drug-using control participants: Drug and monetary rewards. "Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology, 5", 256-262.
* Madden, G. J., Ewan, E. E., & Lagorio, C. H. (2007). Toward an animal model of gambling: Delay discounting and the allure of unpredictable outcomes. "Journal of Gambling Studies, 23", 63-83.
* Perry, J. L., Larson, E. B., German, J. P., Madden, G. J., and Carroll, M. E. (2005). Impulsivity (delay discounting) as a predictor of acquisition of i.v. cocaine self-administration in female rats. "Psychopharmacology, 178", 193-201.
* Petry, N. M., and Casarella, T. (1999). Excessive discounting of delayed rewards in substance abusers with gambling problems. "Drug and Alcohol Dependence, 56", 25-32.
* Poulos, C. X., Le, A. D., and Parker, J. L. (1995). Impulsivity predicts individual susceptibility to high levels of alcohol self administration. "Behavioral Pharmacology, 6", 810-814.
* Vuchinich, R. E., and Simpson, C. A. (1998). Hyperbolic temporal discounting in social drinkers and problem drinkers. "Experimental and Clinical Psychopharmacology, 6", 292-305.
* Rachlin, H. (2000). "The Science of Self-Control" Cambridge;London: Harvard University Press
* Raineri,A., and Rachlin, H. (1993). The effect of temporal constraints on the value of money and other commodities. "Journal of Behavioral Decision-Making, 6," 77-94.


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать реферат

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Discounting — For discounting in the sense of downplaying or dismissing, see Minimisation (psychology). For the band of the same name, see Discount (band). See also: Discounts and allowances Discounting is a financial mechanism in which a debtor obtains the… …   Wikipedia

  • David Laibson — in 2007. Born 26 June 1966 (1966 06 26) (age 45) Nationality …   Wikipedia

  • Behavioral economics — and its related area of study, behavioral finance, use social, cognitive and emotional factors in understanding the economic decisions of individuals and institutions performing economic functions, including consumers, borrowers and investors,… …   Wikipedia

  • Discounted cash flow — Excel spreadsheet uses Free cash flows to estimate stock s Fair Value and measure the sensibility of WACC and Perpetual growth In finance, discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis is a method of valuing a project, company, or asset using the concepts… …   Wikipedia

  • Efficient-market hypothesis — Financial markets Public market Exchange Securities Bond market Fixed income Corporate bond Government bond Municipal bond …   Wikipedia

  • Discount function — A discount function is used in economic models to describe the weights placed on rewards received at different points in time. For example, if time is discrete and utility is time separable, with the discount function f(t) with c(t) defined as… …   Wikipedia

  • Dynamic inconsistency — In economics, dynamic inconsistency, or time inconsistency, describes a situation where a decision maker s preferences change over time in such a way that what is preferred at one point in time is inconsistent with what is preferred at another… …   Wikipedia

  • Discounted utility — is an economics term in which economists, accountants, underwriters, and other financial analysts include the future discounted value of a good in its present value. This can be thought of as the idea of impatience, or the valuing of future… …   Wikipedia

  • Time value of money — The time value of money is the value of money figuring in a given amount of interest earned over a given amount of time. The time value of money is the central concept in finance theory. For example, $100 of today s money invested for one year… …   Wikipedia

  • Partha Dasgupta — Sir Partha Sarathi Dasgupta (* 17. November 1942 in Dhaka, damals Indien, heute Bangladesch) ist ein Wirtschaftswissenschaftler. Inhaltsverzeichnis 1 Leben und Wirken 2 Auszeichnungen 3 Mitgliedschaften …   Deutsch Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”