Taylor rule

Taylor rule

The Taylor rule is a modern monetary policy rule proposed by economist John B. Taylor that stipulates how much the central bank should change the nominal interest rate in response to divergences of actual GDP from "potential" GDP and divergences of actual rates of inflation from a "target" rate of inflation. [ [http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/Papers/Discretion.PDF Taylor, John B. (1993): "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39, 195-214.] ] The rule can be written as follows:

i_t = pi_t + r_t^* + a_pi ( pi_t - pi_t^* ) + a_y ( y_t - ar y_t )

In this equation, i_t is the target short-term nominal interest rate (e.g. the federal funds rate in the US), pi_t is the rate of inflation as measured by the GDP deflator, pi^*_t is the desired rate of inflation, r_t^* is the assumed equilibrium real interest rate, y_t is the logarithm of real GDP, and ar y_t is the logarithm of potential output, as determined by a linear trend (Taylor, 1993).

Interpretation

According to the rule, both a_{pi} and a_y should be positive (as a rough rule of thumb, Taylor's 1993 paper proposed setting a_{pi}=a_y=0.5). That is, the rule "recommends" a relatively high interest rate (a "tight" monetary policy) when inflation is above its target or when the economy is above its full employment level, and a relatively low interest rate ("easy" monetary policy) in the opposite situations.

Sometimes monetary policy goals may conflict, as in the case of stagflation, when inflation is above its target while the economy is below full employment. In such a situation, the rule offers guidance on how to balance these competing considerations in setting an appropriate level for the interest rate. In particular, by specifying a_{pi}>0, the Taylor rule says that the central bank should raise the nominal interest rate by more than one percentage point for each percentage point increase in inflation. In other words, since the real interest rate is (approximately) the nominal interest rate minus inflation, stipulating a_{pi}>0 is equivalent to saying that when inflation rises, the real interest rate should be increased.

Although the Fed does not explicitly follow the rule, many analyses show that the rule does a fairly accurate job of describing how US monetary policy actually has been conducted during the past decade under Alan Greenspan. [Clarida, Richard; Mark Gertler; and Jordi Galí (2000), 'Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: theory and some evidence.' "Quarterly Journal of Economics" 115. pp. 147-180.] [Citation |last=Lowenstein |first=Roger |title=The Education of Ben Bernanke | newspaper=The New York Times |date=2008-01-20 |year=2008 |url=http://www.nytimes.com/2008/01/20/magazine/20Ben-Bernanke-t.html] Similar observations have been made about central banks in other developed economies, both in countries like Canada and New Zealand that have officially adopted inflation targeting rules, and in others like Germany where the central bank's policy did not officially target the inflation rate. [Bernanke, Ben, and Ilian Mihov (1997), 'What does the Bundesbank target?' "European Economic Review" 41 (6), pp. 1025-53.] [Clarida, Richard; Mark Gertler; and Jordi Galí (1998), 'Monetary policy rules in practice: some international evidence.' "European Economic Review" 42 (6), pp. 1033-67.] This observation has been cited by many economists as a reason why inflation has remained under control and the economy has been relatively stable in most developed countries since the 1980s.

During an Econtalk podcast Taylor explained the rule in simple terms using three variables: inflation rate, GDP growth, and the interest rate. If inflation were to rise by 1%, the proper response would be to raise the interest rate by 1.5% (Taylor explains that it doesn't always need to be exactly 1.5%, but being larger than 1% is essential). If GDP falls by 1% relative to its growth path, than the proper response is to cut the interest rate by .5%. [ [http://www.econtalk.org/archives/2008/08/john_taylor_on.html Econtalk podcast, Aug. 18, 2008] , interview conducted by Russell Roberts, sponsored by the [http://www.econlib.org/ Library of Economics and Liberty] .]

Critique

Orphanides (2003) claims that the Taylor rule can misguide policy makers since they face real time data. He shows that the Taylor rule matches the US funds rate less perfectly when accounting for these informational limitations and that an activist policy following the Taylor rule would have resulted in an inferior macroeconomic performance during the Great Inflation of the seventies. [Orphanides, A. (2003): "The quest for prosperity without inflation," Journal of Monetary Economics 50, p. 633-663.]

ee also

*Monetary policy
*Inflation targeting

References

External links

* [http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/PolRulLink.htm Resources from John Taylor's web site.]
* [http://www.federalreserve.gov/Pubs/FEDS/2007/200718/200718pap.pdf Federal Reserve paper on the Taylor Rule.]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать реферат

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Taylor — is an English surname and given name meaning tailor . It may also refer to: *Taylor (given name), the given name * See also List of people with surname TaylorPlaces* Australia ** Electoral district of Taylor, state electoral district ** Taylor,… …   Wikipedia

  • Taylor-Regel — Die Taylor Regel ist nach ihrem Erfinder, dem US Ökonomen John B. Taylor, benannt. Ziel der Regel ist, die Geldpolitik bzw. den von der Zentralbank gesetzten Zinssatz zu bestimmen.[1] John B. Taylor …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Taylor — (spr. tēler), 1) Jeremy, anglikan. Geistlicher, geb. 15. Aug. 1613 in Cambridge, gest. 13. Aug. 1667 in Lisburn, 1637 Kaplan König Karls I., nach der Revolution Privatmann, 1660 Bischof von Down und Camor, war einer der hervorragendsten Prediger… …   Meyers Großes Konversations-Lexikon

  • Taylor [2] — Taylor (spr. Tehl r), 1) Thomas, geb. zu Cambridge; war erst Prediger zu Reading u. dann in London u. starb 1632; er schr.: Commentary of the epistle of Paul to Titus and to Philemon; Exposition of the 12 chapter of Johns Relevation; The parable… …   Pierer's Universal-Lexikon

  • Taylor v. Standard Gas Co. — Taylor v. Standard Gas Co. 306 U.S. 307 (1939) is an important case decided by the U.S. Supreme Court, which laid down the Deep Rock doctrine as a rule of bankruptcy and corporate law. The rule requires that, where a subsidiary corporation… …   Wikipedia

  • Taylor v. Caldwell — 3 B. S. 826, 122 Eng. Rep. 309 (1863), is a famous English legal case which established the doctrine of impossibility in contract law. Facts Defendants Caldwell Bishop owned Surrey Gardens Music Hall, and agreed to rent it out to the plaintiffs …   Wikipedia

  • Rule of 72 — In finance, the rule of 72, the rule of 70 and the rule of 69 are methods for estimating an investment s doubling time. The number in the title is divided by the interest percentage per period to get the approximate number of periods needed for… …   Wikipedia

  • Taylor, Jeremy — (1613–67)    Bishop and Devotional Writer.    Taylor was born and educated in Cambridge. After ordination he came to the attention of Archbishop laud who nominated him to a fellowship at All Souls’, Oxford, and he was appointed to be a chaplain… …   Who’s Who in Christianity

  • Taylor's theorem — In calculus, Taylor s theorem gives a sequence of approximations of a differentiable function around a given point by polynomials (the Taylor polynomials of that function) whose coefficients depend only on the derivatives of the function at that… …   Wikipedia

  • Taylor, Jeremy — ▪ British author baptized Aug. 15, 1613, Cambridge, Cambridgeshire, Eng. died Aug. 13, 1667, Lisburn, County Antrim, Ire.       Anglican clergyman and writer.       Taylor was educated at the University of Cambridge and was ordained in 1633. He… …   Universalium

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”