Indifference curve

Indifference curve

In microeconomic theory, an indifference curve is a graph showing different bundles of goods, each measured as to quantity, between which a consumer is "indifferent." That is, at each point on the curve, the consumer has no preference for one bundle over another. In other words, they are all equally preferred. One can equivalently refer to each point on the indifference curve as rendering the same level of utility (satisfaction) for the consumer. Utility is then a device to represent preferences rather than something from which preferences come. [harvnb|Geanakoplis|1987|p=117] The main use of indifference curves is in the representation of potentially observable demand patterns for individual consumers over commodity bundles. [harvnb|Böhm|Haller|1987|p=785]

History

The theory of indifference curves was developed by Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, Vilfredo Pareto and others in the first part of the 20th century. The theory can be derived from ordinal utility theory, which posits that individuals can always rank any consumption bundles by order of preference.

Map and properties of indifference curves

A graph of indifference curves for an individual consumer associated with different utility levels is called an indifference map. Points yielding different utility levels are each associated with distinct indifference curves. An indifference curve describes a set of personal preferences and so can vary from person to person.

Indifference curves are typically represented to be:
* 1. defined only in the positive (+, +) quadrant of commodity-bundle quantities.
* 2. negatively sloped. That is, as quantity consumed of one good (X) increases, total satisfaction would increase if not offset by a decrease in the quantity consumed of the other good (Y). Equivalently, satiation, such that more of either good (or both) is equally preferred to no increase, is excluded. (If utility "U = f(x, y)", "U", in the third dimension, does not have a local maximum for any "x" and "y" values.)
* 3. complete, such that all points on an indifference curve are ranked equally preferred and ranked either more or less preferred than every other point not on the curve. So, with (2), no two curves can intersect (otherwise non-satiation would be violated).
* 4. transitive with respect to points on distinct indifference curves. That is, if each point on "I2" is (strictly) preferred to each point on "I1", and each point on "I3" is preferred to each point on "I2", each point on "I3" is preferred to each point on "I1". A negative slope and transitivity exclude indifference curves crossing, since straight lines from the origin on both sides of where they crossed would give opposite and intransitive preference rankings.
* 5. (strictly) convex (sagging from below). With (2), convex preferences implies a bulge toward the origin of the indifference curve. As a consumer decreases consumption of one good in successive units, successively larger doses of the other good are required to keep satisfaction unchanged.

Assumptions

Let "a", "b", and "c" be bundles (vectors) of goods, such as ("x", "y") combinations above, with possibly different quantities of each respective good in the different bundles. The first assumption is necessary for a well-defined representation of stable preferences for the consumer as agent; the second assumption is convenient.

Rationality (called an ordering relationship in a more general mathematical context): Completeness + transitivity. For given preference rankings, the consumer can choose the best bundle(s) consistently among "a", "b", and "c" from lowest on up.

Continuity: This means that you can choose to consume any amount of the good. For example, I could drink 11 mL of soda, or 12 mL, or 132 mL. I am not confined to drinking 2 liters or nothing. See also continuous function in mathematics.

Of the remaining properties above, suppose, property (5) (convexity) is violated by a bulge of the indifference curves "out from" the origin for a particular consumer with a given budget constraint. Consumer theory then implies zero consumption for one of the two goods, say good Y, in equilibrium on the consumer's budget constraint. This would exemplify a corner solution. Further, decreases in the price of good Y over a certain range might leave quantity demanded unchanged at zero beyond which further price decreases switched all consumption and income away from X and to Y. The eccentricity of such an implication suggests why convexity is typically assumed.

Application

* Consumer theory uses indifference curves and budget constraints to generate consumer demand curves.

Examples of Indifference Curves

In Figure 1, the consumer would rather be on "I3" than "I2", and would rather be on "I2" than "I1", but does not care where he/she is on a given indifference curve. The slope of an indifference curve (in absolute value), known by economists as the marginal rate of substitution, shows the rate at which consumers are willing to give up one good in exchange for more of the other good. For "most" goods the marginal rate of substitution is not constant so their indifference curves are curved. The curves are convex to the origin, describing the negative substitution effect. As price rises for a fixed money income, the consumer seeks less the expensive substitute at a lower indifference curve. The substitution effect is reinforced through the income effect of lower real income (Beattie-LaFrance). An example of a utility function that generates indifference curves of this kind is the Cobb-Douglas function scriptstyle Uleft(x,y ight)=x^alpha y^{1-alpha}, 0 leq alpha leq 1.

If two goods are perfect substitutes then the indifference curves will have a constant slope since the consumer would be willing to trade at a fixed ratio. The marginal rate of substitution between perfect substitutes is likewise constant. An example of a utility function that is associated with indifference curves like these would be scriptstyle Uleft(x,y ight)=alpha x + eta y.

If two goods are perfect complements then the indifference curves will be L-shaped. An example would be something like if you had a cookie recipe that called for 3 cups flour to 1 cup sugar. No matter how much extra flour you had, you still could not make more cookie dough without more sugar. Another example of perfect complements is a left shoe and a right shoe. The consumer is no better off having several right shoes if she has only one left shoe. Additional right shoes have zero marginal utility without more left shoes. The marginal rate of substitution is either zero or infinite. An example of the type of utility function that has an indifference map like that above is scriptstyle Uleft(x,y ight)= min { alpha x, eta y }.

The different shapes of the curves imply different responses to a change in price as shown from demand analysis in consumer theory. The results will only be stated here. A price-budget-line change that kept a consumer in equilibrium on the same indifference curve::in Fig. 1 would reduce quantity demanded of a good smoothly as price rose relatively for that good. :in Fig. 2 would have either no effect on quantity demanded of either good (at one end of the budget constraint) or would change quantity demanded from one end of the budget constraint to the other.:in Fig. 3 would have no effect on equilibrium quantities demanded, since the budget line would rotate around the corner of the indifference curve.



Preference relations and utility

Choice theory formally represents consumers by a preference relation, and use this representation to derive indifference curves.

The idea of an indifference curve is a straightforward one: If a consumer was equally satisfied with 1 apple and 4 bananas, 2 apples and 2 bananas, or 5 apples and 1 banana, these combinations would all lie on the same indifference curve.

Preference relations

Let:A; = a set of mutually exclusive alternatives among which a consumer can choose:a; and b; = generic elements of A;. In the language of the example above, the set A; is made of combinations of apples and bananas. The symbol a; is one such combination, such as 1 apple and 4 bananas and b; is another combination such as 2 apples and 2 bananas. A preference relation, denoted succeq, is a binary relation define on the set A;.

The statement:asucceq b;is described as 'a; is weakly preferred to b;.' That is, a; is at least as good as b; (in preference satisfaction).

The statement :asim b;is described as 'a; is weakly preferred to b;, and b; is weakly preferred to a;.' That is, one is "indifferent" to the choice of a; or b;, meaning not that they are unwanted but that they are equally good in satisfying preferences.

The statement :asucc b;is described as 'a; is weakly preferred to b;, but b; is not weakly preferred to a;.' One says that 'a; is strictly preferred to b;.'

The preference relation succeq is complete if all pairs a,b; can be ranked. The relation is a transitive relation if whenever asucceq b; and bsucceq c,; then asucceq c;.

Consider a particular element of the set A;, such as a_0;. Suppose one builds the list of all other elements of A; which are indifferent, in the eyes of the consumer, to a_0;. Denote the first element in this list by a_1;, the second by a_2; and so on... The set {a_i:igeq 0} forms an indifference curve since a_isim a_j; for all i,jgeq 0;.

Formal link to utility theory

In the example above, an element a; of the set A; is made of two numbers: The number of apples, call it x,; and the number of bananas, call it y.;

In utility theory, the "utility function" of an agent is a function that ranks "all" pairs of consumption bundles by order of preference ("completeness") such that any set of three or more bundles forms a transitive relation. This means that for each bundle left(x,y ight) there is a unique relation, Uleft(x,y ight), representing the utility (satisfaction) relation associated with left(x,y ight). The relation left(x,y ight) o Uleft(x,y ight) is called the utility function. The range of the function is a set of real numbers. The actual values of the function have no importance. Only the ranking of those values has content for the theory. More precisely, if U(x,y)geq U(x',y'), then the bundle left(x,y ight) is described as at least as good as the bundle left(x',y' ight). If Uleft(x,y ight)>Uleft(x',y' ight), the bundle left(x,y ight) is described as strictly preferred to the bundle left(x',y' ight).

Consider a particular bundle left(x_0,y_0 ight) and take the total derivative of Uleft(x,y ight) about this point:

:dUleft(x_0,y_0 ight)=U_1left(x_0,y_0 ight)dx+U_2left(x_0,y_0 ight)dy or, without loss of generality,

:frac{dUleft(x_0,y_0 ight)}{dx}= U_1(x_0,y_0).1+ U_2(x_0,y_0)frac{dy}{dx} (Eq. 1)

where U_1left(x,y ight) is the partial derivative of Uleft(x,y ight) with respect to its first argument, evaluated at left(x,y ight). (Likewise for U_2left(x,y ight).)

The indifference curve through left(x_0,y_0 ight) must deliver at each bundle on the curve the same utility level as bundle left(x_0,y_0 ight). That is, when preferences are represented by a untility function, the indifference curves are the level curves of the utility function. Therefore, if one is to change the quantity of x, by dx,, without moving off the indifference curve, one must also change the quantity of y, by an amount dy, such that, in the end, there is no change in "U"::frac{dUleft(x_0,y_0 ight)}{dx}= 0, or, substituting "0" into "(Eq. 1)" above to solve for "dy/dx"::frac{dUleft(x_0,y_0 ight)}{dx} = 0Leftrightarrowfrac{dy}{dx}=-frac{U_1(x_0,y_0)}{U_2(x_0,y_0)}. Thus, the ratio of marginal utilities gives the absolute value of the slope of the indifference curve at point left(x_0,y_0 ight). This ratio is called the marginal rate of substitution between x, and y,.

Examples

Linear utility

If the utility function is of the form Uleft(x,y ight)=alpha x+eta y then the marginal utility of x, is U_1left(x,y ight)=alpha and the marginal utility of y, is U_2left(x,y ight)=eta. The slope of the indifference curve is, therefore, :frac{dx}{dy}=-frac{eta}{alpha}.Observe that the slope does not depend on x, or y,: Indifference curves are straight lines.

Cobb-Douglas utility

If the utility function is of the form Uleft(x,y ight)=x^alpha y^{1-alpha} the marginal utility of x, is U_1left(x,y ight)=alpha left(x/y ight)^{alpha-1} and the marginal utility of y, is U_2left(x,y ight)=(1-alpha) left(x/y ight)^{alpha}. The marginal rate of substitution, and therefore the slope of the indifference curve is then:frac{dx}{dy}=-frac{1-alpha}{alpha}left(frac{x}{y} ight).

CES utility

A general CES (Constant Elasticity of Substitution) form is :U(x,y)=left(alpha x^ ho +(1-alpha)y^ ho ight)^{1/ ho}where alphain(0,1) and holeq 1. (The Cobb-Douglas is a special case of the CES utility, with ho=0,.) The marginal utilities are given by:U_1(x,y)=alpha left(alpha x^ ho +(1-alpha)y^ ho ight)^{left(1/ ho ight)-1} x^{ ho-1}and:U_2(x,y)=(1-alpha)left(alpha x^ ho +(1-alpha)y^ ho ight)^{left(1/ ho ight)-1} y^{ ho-1}.Therefore, along an indifference curve, :frac{dx}{dy}=-frac{1-alpha}{alpha}left(frac{x}{y} ight)^{1- ho}.These examples might be useful for modelling individual or aggregate demand.

See also

* Budget constraint
* Level curve
* Consumer theory
*Convex preferences
* "Homo economicus"
* Microeconomics
* Rationality

Notes

References

*Bruce R. Beattie and Jeffrey T. LaFrance, “The Law of Demand versus Diminishing Marginal Utility” (2006). "Review of Agricultural Economics". 28 (2), pp. 263-271.
*Volker Böhm and Hans Haller (1987). "demand theory," "The ", v. 1, pp. 785-92.
*John Geanakoplos (1987). "Arrow-Debreu model of general equilibrium," "The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics", v. 1, pp. 116-24.

External links

* [http://students.washington.edu/fuleky/anatomy/anatomy.html Anatomy of Cobb-Douglas Type Utility Functions in 3D]
* [http://students.washington.edu/fuleky/anatomy/anatomy2.html Anatomy of CES Type Utility Functions in 3D]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно сделать НИР?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Indifference curve — The graphical expression of a utility function, where the horizontal axis measures risk and the vertical axis measures expected return. The curve connects all portfolios with the same utilities according to . and . The New York Times Financial… …   Financial and business terms

  • indifference curve — The expression in a graph of a utility function, where the horizontal axis measures risk and the vertical axis measures expected return. The curve connects all portfolios with the same utility. Bloomberg Financial Dictionary * * * indifference… …   Financial and business terms

  • indifference curve — ▪ economics       in economics, graph showing various combinations of two things (usually consumer goods) that yield equal satisfaction or utility to an individual. Developed by the Irish born British economist Francis Y. Edgeworth (Edgeworth,… …   Universalium

  • Indifference Curve — A diagram depicting equal levels of utility (satisfaction) for a consumer faced with various combinations of goods. As an example, consider the diagram above. This consumer would be most satisfied with any combination of products along curve U3.… …   Investment dictionary

  • indifference curve — noun : a curve used in economics to indicate all possible comparative quantities of goods or services equally demanded by or of equal use to a consumer …   Useful english dictionary

  • indifference curve — noun a graph showing different bundles of goods, each measured as to quantity, between which a consumer is indifferent …   Wiktionary

  • indifference curve — graph that depicts the basket of goods that brings a customer the same benefit (Economics) …   English contemporary dictionary

  • indifference curve — /ɪnˈdɪfrəns kɜv/ (say in difruhns kerv) noun a graph, whose co ordinates represent the quantities of alternative goods and services that tend to leave the consumer indifferent in making a choice because he or she judges them of equal value …  

  • indifference curve — /ɪn dɪf(ə)rəns kɜ:v/ noun a line on a graph that joins various points, each point representing a combination of two commodities, each combination giving the customer equal satisfaction …   Marketing dictionary in english

  • Community indifference curve — A community indifference curve is an illustration of different combinations of commodity quantities that would bring a whole community the same level of utility. The model can be used to describe any community, such as a town or an entire nation …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”