Choice model simulation

Choice model simulation

Although the concept choice models is widely understood and practiced these days, it is often difficult to acquire hands-on knowledge in simulating choice models. While many stat packages provide useful tools to simulate, researchers attempting to test and simulate new choice models with data often encounter problems from as simple as scaling parameter to misspecification. This article goes beyond simply defining discrete choice models. Rather, it aims at providing a comprehensive overview of how to simulate such models in computer.

Contents

Defining choice set

When a researcher has some consumer choice data in his/her hand and tries to construct a choice model and simulate it against the data, he/she needs to first define a choice set. A Choice Set in discrete choice models is defined to be finite, exhaustive, and mutually exclusive. For instance, consider households' choice of how many laptops to own. The researcher can define the choice set depending on the nature of the data and the interpretation they wish to draw, as long as it satisfies three properties mentioned above. Some examples of choice sets that meet the categories are the following:

  1. 0 , 1, More than 1 laptop
  2. 0 , 1 , 2 , More than 2 laptops
  3. Less than 2 , 2 , 3 , 4 , More than 4 laptops

Defining consumer utility

Suppose a student is trying to decide which pub he/she should go for a beer after his/her last final exam. Suppose there are two pubs in the town of the college: an Irish pub and an American pub. The researcher wishes to predict which pub he/she will choose based on the price (P) of beer and the distance (D) to each pub, assuming they are known to the researcher. Then, the consumer utilities for choosing the Irish pub and the American pub can be defined:

 U_i =\alpha P_i + \beta D_i + \varepsilon_i\, (1)
 U_a =\alpha P_a + \beta D_a + \varepsilon_a\, (2)

where  \varepsilon captures unobserved variables that affect consumer utilities.

Defining choice probabilities

Once the consumer utilities have been specified, the researcher can derive choice probabilities. Namely, the probability of the student choosing the Irish pub over the American pub is

 
\begin{align}
P_i & = \Pr(U_i > U_a) 
= \Pr( \alpha P_i + \beta D_i + \varepsilon_i >  \alpha P_a + \beta D_a + \varepsilon_a ) \\  
& = \Pr( \varepsilon_i - \varepsilon_a >  \alpha P_a + \beta D_a - \alpha P_i - \beta D_i  )
\end{align}

Denoting the observed portion of the utility function as V,

Pi = Pr(εi − εa > VaVi) (3)

In the end, discrete choice modeling comes down to specifying the distribution of  \varepsilon (or \varepsilon_i - \varepsilon_a) and solving the integral over the range of  \varepsilon to calculate Pi. Extending this to more general situations with

  1. N consumers (n = 1, 2, …, N),
  2. J choices of consumption (j = 1, 2, … , J),

The choice probability of consumer n choosing j can be written as

Pnj = Pr(Unj > Uni) (4)

for all i other than j

Identification

1. What's irrelevant

From equation (4), it's obvious that Pnj does not change as long as the inequality in the probability argument on the right side stays the same. In other words, adding or multiplying by a constant to all Un1...UnJ does not change the choice probably, thus no change in interpretation.

2. Alternative-specific constants

Unlike adding a constant to all the utilities, adding alternative-specific constants does alter the choice probabilities. Suppose alternative-specific constants Ci and Ca are added to (1) and (2):

 U_i =  C_i + \alpha P_i + \beta D_i + \varepsilon_i\,
 U_a = C_a + \alpha P_a + \beta D_a + \varepsilon_a\,

Then, depending on the value of the estimated alternative-specific constants, the choice probability may change. Also if we write the choice probability in the format of (3),

Pi = Pr(εi − εa > (CaCi) + αPa − αPi + βDa − βDi)

only the difference between CaandCi affects the choice probability (i.e. our estimation can only identify the difference). So it's convenient to normalize all the alternative-specific constants to one of the alternatives. If we normalize to Ci, then we estimate the following model:

 U_i = \alpha P_i + \beta D_i + \varepsilon_i\,
 U_a = (C_a - C_i ) + \alpha P_a + \beta D_a + \varepsilon_a\,

When there are more than 2 choices in the choice set, we can pick any choice i and normalize the alternative-specific constants to that choice by subtracting Ci from all other alternative-specific constants.

3. Sociodemographic variables

In deciding between the Irish pub and the American pub, if the researcher has access to additional sociodemographic variables such as income, they can enter the consumer utility equation in various ways. Denote the student's income as Y. If the researcher believes that the income affects the utility linearly, then

 U_i =  \alpha P_i + \beta D_i + \gamma Y +\varepsilon_i\,

If the researcher believes that the sociodemographic variable interacts with other variable such as price, then the utility can be written as

 U_i =  \alpha P_i/Y + \beta D_i +\varepsilon_i\,

General models

As mentioned earlier, calculation and justification of choice probabilities rely on the properties of the error (i.e. the unobservables) distribution function the researcher specifies. Here is the quick overview of frequently used models that each differs in specification

1. Logit:

  • Assumes unoberseved factors have the same variance with zero correlation across alternatives.
  • iid extreme value unobserved factors
  • The cumulative distribution of difference in extreme values is Logistics function
  • Logistics function has a closed form solution => No simulation necessary.

2. GEV (Generalized extreme value distribution)

  • Allows correlation in unobserved factors across alternatives.
  • iid extreme value unobserved factors
  • The cumulative distribution of difference in extreme values is Logistics function
  • Logistics function has a closed form solution => No simulation necessary.

3. Probit

  • Unobeserved factors have a jointly normal distribution.
  • No closed form for the cumulative distribution of normal distribution. Simulation necessary.

4. Mixed logit

  • Allows any distribution in unobserved factors
  • No closed form for the cumulative distribution of normal distribution. Simulation necessary.

References

  • A Nevo (2000). "Practitioners Guide to Estimation of Random Coefficients Logit Models of Demand," Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 9(4), 513–548
  • Kenneth E. Train, " Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation", Massachusetts: Cambridge University Press, 2003.

Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно решить контрольную?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Choice modelling — attempts to model the decision process of an individual or segment in a particular context. Choice modelling may also be used to estimate non market environmental benefits and costs[1]. Well specified choice models are sometimes able to predict… …   Wikipedia

  • Simulation cockpit — Simulation cockpits or simpits are environments designed to replicate a vehicle cockpit. Although many pits commonly designed around an aircraft cockpit, the term is equally valid for train or car projects. Simpit is generally used to refer to… …   Wikipedia

  • Simulation software — is based on the process of imitating a real phenomenon with a set of mathematical formulas. It is, essentially, a program that allows the user to observe an operation through simulation without actually running the program. Simulation software is …   Wikipedia

  • Model-driven architecture — (MDA) is a software design approach for the development of software systems. It provides a set of guidelines for the structuring of specifications, which are expressed as models. Model driven architecture is a kind of domain engineering, and… …   Wikipedia

  • Simulation — Simulator redirects here. For other uses, see Simulator (disambiguation). For other uses, see Simulation (disambiguation). Not to be confused with Stimulation. Wooden mechanical horse simulator during WWI. Simulation is the imitation of some real …   Wikipedia

  • Model (macroeconomics) — A model in macroeconomics is a logical, mathematical, and/or computational framework designed to describe the operation of a national or regional economy, and especially the dynamics of aggregate quantities such as the total amount of goods and… …   Wikipedia

  • Simulation language — A computer simulation language describes the operation of a simulation on a computer. There are two major types of simulation: continuous and discrete event though more modern languages can handle combinations. Most languages also have a… …   Wikipedia

  • model —    by Gary Genosko   Baudrillard s thinking about models had two distinct phases. The first belonged to the period of The System of Objects (1996a [1968]) in which he worked through the difference between models and series; the second emerged in… …   The Baudrillard dictionary

  • Model risk — In finance, model risk is the risk involved in using models to value financial securities.[1] Rebonato considers alternative definitions including: After observing a set of prices for the underlying and hedging instruments, different but… …   Wikipedia

  • Discrete choice — In economics, discrete choice problems involve choices between two or more discrete alternatives, such as entering or not entering the labor market, or choosing between modes of transport. Such choices contrast with standard consumption models in …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”