Discursive dilemma

Discursive dilemma

Discursive dilemma or doctrinal paradox is a paradox in social choice theory which states that aggregating judgements with majority voting might result in a self-contradictory judgement.

P Q R = P & Q R
Judge 1 yes yes yes yes
Judge 2 no yes yes no
Judge 3 yes no yes no
Majority decision yes yes yes no

Assume that a three-member court must decide whether someone is liable for a breach of contract. The judges have to decide which of the following propositions are true:

  • P: the defendant did a certain action;
  • Q: the defendant had a contractual obligation not to do that action;
  • R: the defendant is liable.

Additionally, all judges accept the proposition R \equiv P \and Q, which is the just legal doctrine that you are liable if you breach contract. Each judge makes a consistent (non-contradictory) judgement: they will accept R if and only if they accept both P and Q. As can be seen in the table, if they decide about each proposition by majority vote, the resulting judgement will not necessarily be consistent.

An actual decision-making procedure might be premise-based or conclusion-based. In a premise-based procedure, the judges decide by voting whether the conditions for liability are met. In a conclusion-based procedure, the judges decide directly whether the defendant should be liable. In this formulation, the paradox is that the two procedures don't necessarily lead to the same result.

The discursive dilemma can be seen as a generalization of the Condorcet paradox, as a preference set is just a special kind of proposition set.[clarification needed] Just as the Condorcet paradox can be generalized to Arrow's theorem, List and Pettit argue that the discursive dilemma can be generalized to the List-Pettit theorem, which states that the inconsistency remains for any aggregation method which meets a few natural conditions.

References

External links

  • Judgment aggregation: an introduction and bibliography of the discursive dilemma by Christian List



Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать курсовую

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Collective — For other uses, see Collective (disambiguation). A collective is a group of entities that share or are motivated by at least one common issue or interest, or work together on a specific project(s) to achieve a common objective.[citation needed]… …   Wikipedia

  • Belief revision — is the process of changing beliefs to take into account a new piece of information. The logical formalization of belief revision is researched in philosophy, in databases, and in artificial intelligence for the design of rational agents.What… …   Wikipedia

  • Voting paradox — This article is about the arguably irrational results that can arise in a collective choice among three or more alternatives. For the contention that an individual s vote will probably not affect the outcome, see Paradox of voting. The voting… …   Wikipedia

  • Critical theory — Horkheimer, Adorno, Habermas David Rasmussen HEGEL, MARX AND THE IDEA OF A CRITICAL THEORY Critical theory1 is a metaphor for a certain kind of theoretical orientation which owes its origin to Hegel and Marx, its systematization to Horkheimer and …   History of philosophy

  • Immanuel Kant — Kant redirects here. For other uses, see Kant (disambiguation). See also: Kant (surname) Immanuel Kant Immanuel Kant Full name Immanuel Kant Born 22 April 1724 …   Wikipedia

  • tragedy — /traj i dee/, n., pl. tragedies. 1. a dramatic composition, often in verse, dealing with a serious or somber theme, typically that of a great person destined through a flaw of character or conflict with some overpowering force, as fate or society …   Universalium

  • English literature — Introduction       the body of written works produced in the English language by inhabitants of the British Isles (including Ireland) from the 7th century to the present day. The major literatures written in English outside the British Isles are… …   Universalium

  • Dilemme du prisonnier — Le dilemme du prisonnier est un exemple célèbre de la théorie des jeux caractérisant les situations où deux joueurs auraient intérêt à coopérer, mais où les incitations à trahir l autre sont si fortes que la coopération n est jamais sélectionnée… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Corneille, Pierre — born June 6, 1606, Rouen, France died Oct. 1, 1684, Paris French poet and playwright. He studied law and was a king s counselor in Rouen (1628–50). He wrote his first comedy, Mélite (performed 1629), before he was 20; other comedies followed. He… …   Universalium

  • Harmonium (poetry collection) — Harmonium is a book of poetry by U.S. poet Wallace Stevens. His first book, it was published in 1923 by Knopf in an edition of 1500 copies. He was in middle age at that time, forty four years old. The collection comprises 85 poems, ranging in… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”