Laffer curve

Laffer curve

In economics, the Laffer curve is used to illustrate the idea that increases in the rate of taxation may sometimes decrease tax revenue. Since a 100 percent income tax will generate no revenue (as citizens will have no incentive to work), the optimal tax rate that maximizes government revenue must lie below 100 percent. Increasing taxes beyond that point would decrease tax revenue. The Laffer curve was popularized by Arthur Laffer (b. 1940) in the 1980's. However, the underlying principle has been well known since at least the time of Ibn Khaldun's "Muqaddimah" (1377). In his "General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money", John Maynard Keynes described how past a certain point, increasing taxation would lower revenue and vice versa.John Maynard Keynes, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes (London: Macmillan, Cambridge University Press, 1972).]

The Laffer-curve is central to supply side economics, as it provides an argument for why lowering taxation may actually increase tax revenues. Many economists have questioned the utility of the Laffer Curve in public discourse. According to Nobel prize laureate James Tobin, " [t] he 'Laffer Curve' idea that tax cuts would actually increase revenues turned out to deserve the ridicule with which sober economists had greeted it in 1981."Tobin, J. (Summer 1992). Voodoo Curse. "Harvard International Review, 14", p10, 4p, 1bw.]

Theory

The curve is most easily understood by considering the two extremes of income taxation—0 percent and 100 percent. At the lower extreme, a 0 percent tax rate means the government's revenue is, of course, zero. At the other extreme, where there is a 100 percent tax rate, the government theoretically collects zero revenue because (in a "rational" economic model) taxpayers would change their behavior in response to the tax rate: either they have no incentive to work or they find a way to avoid paying taxes, so the government collects 100% of nothing. (However, the government may still collect some revenue if some taxpayers are not "economically rational", or if tax evasion lowers the effective tax rate.) Somewhere between 0% and 100%, therefore, lies a tax rate that will maximize revenue.

The point at which the curve achieves its maximum is subject to much theoretical speculation. It will vary from one economy to another and depends on the elasticity of supply for labor and various other factors. It is therefore expected to vary with time even in the same economy. Complexities arise when taking into account possible differences in incentive to work for different income groups and when introducing progressive taxation. The structure of the curve may also be changed by other policy decisions, for example, if tax loopholes and off-shore tax shelters are made more readily available by legislation, the point at which revenue begins to decrease with increased taxation will become lower.

The curve is primarily used by advocates who want government to reduce tax rates (such as those on capital gains) and believe that the optimum tax rate is below the current tax rate. In that case, a reduction in tax rates will actually increase government revenue and not need to be offset by decreased government spending or increased borrowing.

History

The idea inherent in the Laffer curve has been described many times prior to Laffer, including:

* The 14th century Arab scholar Ibn Khaldun
* The 18th century politician Alexander Hamilton
* The 19th century French economist Frédéric Bastiat
* The 20th century economist John Maynard Keynes

Note that Laffer himself does not claim credit for the idea, although he does seem to be responsible for popularizing the concept and its implications to policy makers.

Tangible Evidence in the U.S.

In 1924, Secretary of Treasury Andrew Mellon wrote, "It seems difficult for some to understand that high rates of taxation do not necessarily mean large revenue to the Government, and that more revenue may often be obtained by lower rates." Exercising his understanding that "73% of nothing is nothing" he pushed for the reduction of the top income tax bracket from 73% to an eventual 24% (as well as tax breaks for lower brackets). Personal income-tax receipts rose from $719 million in 1921 to over $1 billion in 1929, which supporters attribute to the rate cut. [ Folsom Jr., Burton W., "The Myth of the Robber Barons", page 103. Young America's Foundation, 2007. ]

Context in U.S. history

Laffer himself does not claim to have invented the concept, attributing it to 14th century Muslim scholar Ibn Khaldun and, more recently, to John Maynard Keynes. The term was reportedly coined by Jude Wanniski (a writer for "The Wall Street Journal") after a 1974 afternoon meeting between Laffer, Wanniski, Dick Cheney, Donald Rumsfeld, and his deputy press secretary Grace-Marie Arnett (Wanninski, 2005; Laffer, 2004). In this meeting, Laffer reportedly sketched the curve on a napkin [http://www.polyconomics.com/gallery/Napkin003.jpg] to illustrate the concept, which immediately caught the imaginations of those present. Laffer professes no recollection of this napkin, but writes, "I used the so-called Laffer Curve all the time in my classes and with anyone else who would listen to me" (Laffer, 2004).

The Laffer curve and supply side economics inspired the Kemp-Roth Tax Cut of 1981. Supply-side advocates of tax cuts claimed that lower tax rates would generate more tax revenue because the United States government's marginal income tax rates prior to the legislation were on the "right-hand" side of the curve.

In 2003, the United States Department of the Treasury released a non-partisan economic study [ cite journal|author= [http://www.treasury.gov/offices/tax-policy/offices/ota.shtml Office of Tax Analysis] |publisher=United States Department of the Treasury|title=Revenue Effects of Major Tax Bills|date=2003, rev. Sept 2006|url=http://www.ustreas.gov/offices/tax-policy/library/ota81.pdf|id=Working Paper 81, Table 2|accessdate=2007-11-28] showing that the 1981 tax act produced a major loss in government revenues of almost 3% of GDP. Of course, unless GDP was unaffected by the tax act, this analysis would be misleading, as the predicted increase in revenue might come in the form of increased GDP. Thus revenues could be increased, fixed, or decreased, as a percent of GDP, and the Laffer curve predictions of absolute increased tax revenue, above what otherwise would have occurred, could still be correct.

David Stockman, President Ronald Reagan's budget director during his first administration and one of the early proponents of supply-side economics, maintained that the Laffer curve was not to be taken literally — at least not in the economic environment of the 1980s United States. In "The Triumph of Politics", he writes:

: [T] he whole California gang had taken [the Laffer curve] literally (and primitively). The way they talked, they seemed to expect that once the supply-side tax cut was in effect, additional revenue would start to fall, manna-like, from the heavens. Since January, I had been explaining that there is no literal Laffer curve.

Empirical evidence

Laffer, in an article published at the Heritage Foundation, has pointed to Russia and the Baltic states who have recently instituted a flat tax with rates lower than 35%, and whose economies started growing soon after implementation. He has also referred to the economic success following the Kemp-Roth tax act, the Kennedy tax cuts, the 1920s tax cuts, and the changes in US capital gains tax structure in 1997 as examples of how tax cuts can cause the economy to grow and thus increase tax revenue.cite web|url=http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/bg1765.cfm|title=Laffer, A. (June 1, 2004). "The Laffer Cruve, Past, Present and Future". Retrieved from the Heritage Foundation.|accessdate=2007-12-11] Others have noted that federal revenues, as a percentage of GDP, have remained stable at approximately 19.5% over the period 1950 to 2007 despite significant changes in margin tax rates over the same period. They argue that since federal revenue is proportional to GDP, the key factor in increasing revenue is to increase GDP. [DAVID RANSON, [http://online.wsj.com/public/article_print/SB121124460502305693.html "You Can't Soak the Rich,"] , The Wall Street Journal, May 20, 2008; Page A23]

At least one empirical study, looking at actual historical data on tax rates, GDP, and revenue, placed the revenue-maximizing tax rate (the point at which another marginal tax rate increase would decrease tax revenue) as high as 80%.fact|date=August 2008 Paul Samuelson argues in his popular economic textbook that Reagan was correct in a very limited sense to view the intuition underlying the Laffer curve as accurate, because as a successful actor, Reagan was subject to marginal tax rates as high as 90% during World War II. The point is that in a progressive tax system, any given person's perspective on the validity of the Laffer curve will be influenced by the marginal tax rate to which that person's income is subject.

Current CBO estimates of the effectiveness of the Laffer curve

In 2005, the Congressional Budget Office released a paper called "Analyzing the Economic and Budgetary Effects of a 10 Percent Cut in Income Tax Rates" that casts doubt on the idea that tax cuts ultimately improve the government's fiscal situation. Unlike earlier research, the CBO paper estimates the budgetary impact of possible macroeconomic effects of tax policies, i.e., it attempts to account for how reductions in individual income tax rates might affect the overall future growth of the economy, and therefore influence future government tax revenues; and ultimately, impact deficits or surpluses. The paper's author forecasts the effects using various assumptions (e.g., people's foresight, the mobility of capital, and the ways in which the federal government might make up for a lower percentage revenue). Even in the paper's most generous estimated growth scenario, only 28% of the projected lower tax revenue would be recouped over a 10-year period after a 10% across-the-board reduction in all individual income tax rates. The paper points out that these projected shortfalls in revenue would have to be made up by federal borrowing: the paper estimates that the federal government would pay an extra $200 billion in interest over the decade covered by his analysis.cite web|url=http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/69xx/doc6908/12-01-10PercentTaxCut.pdf|title=CBO. (December 1, 2005). "Analyzing the Economic and Budgetary Effects of a 10 Percent Cut in Income Tax Rates".|accessdate=2007-12-11]

Critics at the libertarian Cato Institute have charged that to support these calculations, the paper assumes that the 10% reduction in individual tax rates would only result in a 1% increase in gross national product, a figure they consider too low for current marginal tax rates in the United States.cite web|url=http://www.cato.org/testimony/ct-sm03182003.html | title=President Bush's Economic Growth Tax Cut | last=Moore | first=Stephen | date=2003-03-18 | publisher=CATO Institute | accessdate=2007-12-11]

Critiques of the Laffer curve

Conventional economic paradigms acknowledge the basic notion of the Laffer curve, but they argue that government was operating on the "left-hand" side of the curve, so a tax cut would thus lower revenue. The central question is the elasticity of work with respect to tax rates. For example, Pecorino (1995) argued that the peak occurred at tax rates around 65%, and summarized the controversy as:

:Just about everyone can agree that if an increase in tax rates leads to a decrease in tax revenues, then taxes are too high. It is also generally agreed that at "some" level of taxation, revenues will turn down. Determining the level of taxation where revenues are maximized is more controversial.Citation |last1=Pecorino|first1=Paul|authorlink=Paul Pecorino|journal=Journal of Monetary Economics|volume=36|number=3|title= [http://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/0304393295012249 Tax rates and tax revenues in a model of growth through human capital accumulation] |year=1995|pages=527-539]

Focus on the wrong economic incentives

Some economists argue that, while it is correct to focus on the problems of incentives in the economy, the problem is not the general level of taxation. The inelasticity of labor supply means that tax rates will have little effect on labor. The focus of analysis should be on the effective use of the labor already available. These economists point to, for instance, principal-agent problems in ensuring staff have appropriate incentives for performance, rather than the level of tax the staff face.Fact|date=July 2008

Incorrect assumptions

The Laffer Curve assumes that the Government will collect no tax at a 100% tax rate because, rationally, no person will choose to carry out work if they receive none of the economic return from that work. However some economists question whether this assumption is correct.Chait, J. (September 10, 2007). Feast of the Wingnuts: How economic crackpots devoured American politics. The New Republic, 237, 27-31] They argue, for example, that in classically structured Communist societies there was an effective 100% tax rate and yet, while these societies may have been highly inefficient, people did continue to work to some extent.

However, in practical Communist societies such as the now-defunct Soviet Union, all workers were paid some meager wage, usually tied to the level of demand for their services much like in capitalist societies. They also were given government subsidized food, public transportation, and housing associated with the level of their occupation and its importance to the central government. Combined, these "benefits" could be considered income.Fact|date=July 2008

The result of these low-paying and highly subsidized systems is a very high effective rate of taxation with little left to the worker in terms of disposable income. Since much of the worker's true productivity is returned to him in a manner not of his choosing and all similar workers receive the same benefits regardless of the degree of their efforts, there is little incentive to produce in terms or quality or quantity. This is the classic case of an economic system operating on the right half of the Laffer curve, where oppressive government taxation severely dampens economic activity. These societies do much more to substantiate the validity of the Laffer curve theory than to disprove it.Fact|date=July 2008

The very low productivity and wage levels of the old Soviet system were the basis of what has been called the "Soviet National Joke": "We pretend to work; they pretend to pay us!".Fact|date=July 2008

The Neo-Laffer curve

A harsher critique of the Laffer Curve can be seen with Martin Gardner's satirical construct, the so-called neo-Laffer Curve. The neo-Laffer curve matches the original curve near the two extremes of 0% and 100%, but rapidly collapses into an incomprehensible snarl of chaos at the middle. Gardner based his curve on actual US economic data collected in a fifty year period by statistician Persi Diaconis.

The satire illustrates the major fallacy commonly committed with the Laffer curve, namely the assumption that the middle is a smooth, concave function merely because the two extreme endpoints are well-defined. A realistic tax curve would most certainly not resemble a smooth parabola or even any other simple function, but rather a very complex curve with many peaks, valleys, and multiple local maxima. Inside the middle, a wide range of various economic factors confound any simplistic attempt at this interpolation.

As a pedagogical tool, a Laffer curve helps illustrate a specific application of the law of diminishing returns, where the inhibitory cost of taxes may eventually outweigh the increased rate of taxation, and thus led to a counterintuitive lower realization of tax revenue. However the Laffer curve should not be taken as a literal model for a tax revenue curve, especially in debates between relatively moderate amounts of taxation. It is in this context that the Laffer curve is often abused, taken as a serious model for tax revenue when it has little to no predictive value in debates between intermediary rates of taxation.Or|date=July 2008

The Neo-Laffer curve is most commonly used to selectively criticize the right half of the Laffer curve. However, it also implies that the left half of the curve should be just as unpredictable (i.e. that raising taxes has an unpredictable effect on revenue).Or|date=July 2008

The Laffer curve in popular culture

* Jackie Mason can be seen making an indirect reference to this phenomenon in "The World According to Me" (while describing Reagan's tax policies).
* Ben Stein spends time explaining this to a class of teenagers in "Ferris Bueller's Day Off".

ee also

* Trickle-down economics
* Supply-side economics
* Reaganomics
* Macroeconomics
* List of economics topics
* Lawrence Kudlow
* Hauser's Law

Notes

External links

* [http://www.epi.org/briefingpapers/168/bp168.pdf Have the Bush tax cuts spurred economic growth? An analysis by economists at the liberal Economic Policy Institute]
* [http://www.brookings.edu/views/op-ed/gale/20030509.htm Analysis of the Bush tax cuts by the centrist Brookings Institution]
* [http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/bg1765.cfm Arthur Laffer describing the Laffer Curve, at the conservative Heritage Foundation]
* [http://logicizer.townhall.com/g/c5ecb3cf-2712-4f5a-ad89-7ae03da99280 The Logic of the Laffer Curve]
* [http://logicizer.townhall.com/g/f48d2bf3-1c51-4592-aa46-191f089d752f Have the Bush Tax Cuts Generated Higher Revenues? Views of conservative Economists]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем сделать НИР

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Laffer Curve — ☆ Laffer Curve [laf′ər ] n. [after A. Laffer (1940 ), U.S. economist, its originator] [also L c ] a graph illustrating a theory which maintains that increasing tax rates beyond a certain point causes a reduction in government revenues by… …   English World dictionary

  • Laffer Curve — Invented by Arthur Laffer, this curve shows the relationship between tax rates and tax revenue collected by governments. The chart below shows the Laffer Curve: The curve suggests that, as taxes increase from low levels, tax revenue collected by… …   Investment dictionary

  • Laffer curve — A curve conjecturing that economic output will increase if marginal tax rates are cut. Named after economist Arthur Laffer. Bloomberg Financial Dictionary * * * Laffer curve Laf‧fer curve [ˈlæfə ˌkɜːv ǁ fər ˌkɜːrv] noun ECONOMICS the idea… …   Financial and business terms

  • Laffer curve — /laf euhr/, Econ. a relationship postulated between tax rates and tax receipts indicating that rates above a certain level actually produce less revenue because they discourage taxable endeavors and vice versa. [1975 80; named after Arthur Laffer …   Universalium

  • Laffer curve — [ lafə] noun Economics a supposed relationship between economic activity and the rate of taxation which suggests that there is an optimum tax rate which maximizes revenue. Origin 1970s: named after the American economist Arthur Laffer …   English new terms dictionary

  • Laffer Curve — /ˈlæfə kɜv/ (say lafuh kerv) noun a theory which states that above a certain point tax rates produce less revenue rather than more because they discourage taxable activities, and vice versa. {named after Arthur Laffer, born 1940, US economist who …  

  • laffer curve —  1980s economic idea, espoused by Arthur Laffer, suggesting that lowering marginal tax rates stimulates increases in output thereby increasing government tax revenue.  See also supplyside economics, dynamic scoring …   American business jargon

  • Laffer curve — / læfə kɜ:v/ noun a chart showing that cuts in tax rates increase output in the economy. Alternatively, increases in tax rates initially produce more revenue and then less as the economy slows down …   Dictionary of banking and finance

  • Laffer curve — noun a graph purporting to show the relation between tax rates and government income; income increases as tax rates increase up to an optimum beyond which income declines • Hypernyms: ↑graph, ↑graphical record …   Useful english dictionary

  • the Laffer Curve — UK US noun [S] ► ECONOMICS, GOVERNMENT the theory that if a country s tax rates are low, the amount of money collected by the government will increase, because companies will be encouraged to invest and do business in that country: »According to… …   Financial and business terms

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”