- Effects of different voting systems under similar circumstances
This article describes an example election using geographical proximity to create hypothetical preferences of a group of voters, and then compares the results of such preferences with ten different
voting systems . It does not, however, address any of the voting systems that are based onproportional representation .Note that the examples given below may not reflect real-world elections, because, among other things, all of the ballots have only four unique sets of preferences.
There is a wide number of possible single-winner
voting systems , each with different strengths and weaknesses. Each system of voting places different demands on voters and offers different opportunities for strategy to affect the winner.Picking the capital city in Tennessee
We can pretend that these are "true preferences" among voters and that this implies how they would vote. However in an actual election, within a specific voting system, there will be incentives to vote differently (compromising) to improve influence for an acceptable winner.
One-vote systems
Two systems, plurality and runoff voting, allow voters to offer only one vote at a time. The runoff system is two (or more) sequential plurality counts with candidate elimination between.
These are simple systems to vote because they only have to consider one top choice at a time, but require strategies of compromise when there is more than one "good" choice available.
Plurality voting system
:"Winner: Memphis"
In the
plurality voting system each voter is allowed to vote for one candidate, and the winner of the election is whichever candidate represents a plurality of voters by receiving the largest number of votes. This makes the plurality voting system among the simplest of all voting systems.In this example, if voting follows sincere preferences, Memphis is selected with the most votes. Note that this system does not require that the winner have a majority, but only a
plurality . That is, Memphis wins because it has the most votes, even though more than half of the voters preferred another option "and" in all other regions Memphis was the last place choice.Runoff voting (two-round runoff)
:"Winner: Nashville"
In runoff voting there first is a preliminary election, where voters select their preferred candidate. If a candidate reaches the election threshold (usually fifty percent of the valid votes, plus one), they are elected. Otherwise, the top candidates (usually the top two) are placed on a secondary ballot. Whoever receives the most votes on the second ballot is declared elected.
In this example, assuming each voter voted for his preferred city (for a more sophisticated approach, see below), the first ballot results would be as follows:
*Memphis: 42%
*Nashville: 26%
*Knoxville: 17%
*Chattanooga: 15%In a two round runoff, Knoxville and Chattanooga are eliminated, while Nashville and Memphis advance to the second ballot.
The voters from Knoxville and Chattanooga prefer Nashville, because it is closer, over Memphis, so the results of the second ballot would be:
*Nashville: 58%
*Memphis: 42%Nashville would then be declared the winner.
Note on strategy: A two round runoff encourages candidates to unite to make the top two cut. Since Chattanooga and Knoxville both prefer each other second, knowing their divided vote might eliminate them both, they might work together before the election and decide for only Chattanooga to run. That would cause the defeat of Nashville (third place) and Chattanooga could win the final runoff round against Memphis. Something similar would happen with a multi-round elimination ballot, where only the last-place finisher is eliminated.
Potential for tactical voting
The runoff system encourages voters to "compromise" by not voting for their favorite candidate in their first round. In the above two-round example, if all voters from Chattanooga "compromised" for Knoxville in the first round, Knoxville would advance to the second round, where it would defeat Memphis. This would be a better result for the Chattanooga voters than sincere voting would get them. The Memphis supporters voters could respond by voting for Nashville instead of Memphis as a way to prevent Knoxville or Chattanooga winning. Plurality voting also allows this possibility; however, it is much less likely, given that more than two candidates often have to combine forces to win against a candidate with a near-majority. In the above example, all three cities would have had to collude in order to defeat Memphis.
Runoff voting can also encourage voters to vote for "pushovers", in order to set up a more favorable second-round matchup.
Rank preference voting systems
Rank preference systems allow voters to rank all the candidates from highest to lowest preference.
See:
Preferential voting Instant-runoff voting IRV (one-vote elimination runoff)
:"Winner: Knoxville"
In
instant-runoff voting first choices are tallied. If no candidate has the support of a majority of voters, the candidate with the least support is eliminated. A second round of counting takes place, with the votes of supporters of the eliminated candidate now counting for their second choice candidate. After a candidate is eliminated, he or she may not receive any more votes. This process of counting and eliminating is repeated until one candidate has over half the votes.The
Sri Lankan supplementary vote may be understood both as a special variant ofInstant-runoff voting (also known as the "alternative vote") in which there are only two rounds of counting and the voter is restricted to expressing only a first, second, and third preference, and of runoff voting (also known as the two-round system) in which both "rounds" may occur without the need for a second poll.Assuming each voter votes according to their sincere preferences (for a more sophisticated approach, see below), Nashville and Memphis would receive the most votes and advance to the second round.
The second preference of voters from Chattanooga is for Knoxville. However, Knoxville has been eliminated, so the votes must be transferred to the third choice of Chattanooga voters: Nashville, which remains in the race. The second preference of voters from Knoxville is for Chattanooga. Chattanooga has been eliminated so their votes also transfer to their third choice--again, Nashville.
On the second and final count, therefore, all the votes from the two eliminated candidates transfer to Nashville. Nashville now has more votes than Memphis and so Nashville is declared the winner. Note that under "conventional" SV the winner would have been Memphis.
Coombs' method (least-disliked runoff)
:"Winner: Nashville"
Coombs' Method Election Results City Round 1 Round 2 First Last First Last Memphis 42 58 420Nashville 26 0 2668Chattanooga 15 0 15 Knoxville 17 42 17 Coombs' method if one candidate is ranked first by an absolute majority of the voters, then this is the winner. Otherwise votes are tallied for the "lowest preferred" non-eliminated candidate from each ballot. The candidate with the most votes is eliminated. (This method usually requires full rank preferences to be given on every ballot.)Coombs' method can also be equivalently run like instant-runoff voting with multiple votes counted per ballot. For each ballot, a candidate marked above nth place is given a point (among n candidates remaining in a given round). This counting approach allows truncated preference ballots to be counted, since ranked candidates will always have more votes than unranked candidates.
Assuming all of the voters vote sincerely (strategic voting is discussed below), the results would be as follows, by percentage:
* In the first round, no candidate has an absolute majority of first place votes (51).
* Memphis, having the most last place votes (26+15+17=58), is therefore eliminated.
* In the second round, Memphis is out of the running, and so must be factored out. Memphis was ranked first on Group A's ballots, so the second choice of Group A, Nashville, gets an additional 42 first place votes, giving it an absolute majority of first place votes (68 versus 15+17=32) and making it thus the winner. Note that the last place votes are disregarded in the final round.Note that although Coomb's method chose the
Condorcet winner here, this is not necessarily the case.Borda count (ranked scoring)
:"Winner: Nashville"
Note that absolute counts of votes can be used as well as the percentages of the total number of votes; it makes no difference.
Sort
The votes are then sorted. The largest majority is "Chattanooga over Knoxville"; 83% of thevoters prefer Chattanooga. Nashville (68%) beats both Chattanooga and Knoxville by a scoreof 68% over 32% (an exact tie, which is unlikely in real life for this many voters). Since Chattanooga > Knoxville, and they're the losers, Nashville vs. Knoxville will be added first, followed by Nashville vs. Chattanooga.
Thus, the pairs from above would be sorted this way:
Lock
The pairs are then locked in order, skipping any pairsthat would create a cycle:
* Lock Chattanooga over Knoxville.
* Lock Nashville over Knoxville.
* Lock Nashville over Chattanooga.
* Lock Nashville over Memphis.
* Lock Chattanooga over Memphis.
* Lock Knoxville over Memphis.In this case, no cycles are created by any of thepairs, so every single one is locked in.
Every "lock in" would add another arrow to thegraph showing the relationship between the candidates.Here is the final graph (where arrows point fromthe winner).
In this example, Nashville is the winner using RP.
Ambiguity resolution example
Let's say there was an ambiguity. For a simple situation involving candidates A, B, and C.
* A > B 68%
* B > C 72%
* C > A 52%In this situation we "lock in" the majorities starting with the greatest one first.
* Lock B > C
* Lock A > B
* We don't lock in the final C > A as it creates an ambiguity.Therefore, A is the winner.
Summary
In the example election, the winner is Nashville. This would be true for any
Condorcet method . Using theplurality election system system and some other systems, Memphis would have won the election by having the most people, even though Nashville won every simulated pairwise election outright. Usinginstant-runoff voting in this example would have resulted in Knoxville winning, even though more people preferred Nashville over Knoxville.Multiple vote systems (ratings)
These two systems, Approval and Range voting, allow voters to evaluate each candidate independently and assign point scores to each candidate. Approval is a limited range system with zero or one points for each candidate.
In these systems, voters are free to offer honest assessment of their strength of support of all candidates. However voters are also rewarded by "exaggerating" their ratings to maximize the votes for acceptable candidates over unacceptable ones.
Approval voting can be considered a
range voting system that recognizes only this strategic approach of maximizing support for acceptable over unacceptable candidates.Approval (yes/no rating)
In
Approval voting the voters can vote for as many or as few candidates as desired. The candidate with the most votes wins.In this example, supposing that voters voted for their two favorite candidates, the results would be as follows (a more sophisticated approach to voting is discussed below):
*Memphis: 42 total votes
*Nashville: 68 total votes (wins)
*Chattanooga: 58 total votes
*Knoxville: 32 total votesPotential for tactical voting
Approval voting passes the
monotonicity criterion , in that voting for a candidate never lowers that candidate's chance of winning. Indeed, there is never a reason for a voter to tactically vote for a candidate X without voting for all candidates he or she prefers to candidate X. It is also never necessary for a voter to vote for a candidate liked "less" than X in order to elect X.However, as approval voting does not offer a single method of expressing sincere preferences, but rather a plethora of them, voters are encouraged to analyze their fellow voters' preferences and use that information to decide which candidates to vote for. This feature of approval voting makes it difficult for theoreticians to predict how approval will play out in practice.
One good tactic is to vote for every candidate the voter prefers to the leading candidate, and to also vote for the leading candidate if that candidate is preferred to the current second-place candidate. When all voters use this tactic, there is a good chance that the Condorcet winner will be elected. It should be noted that approval voting does not satisfy the
Condorcet criterion . It is even possible that a Condorcet loser can be elected.In the above election, if Chattanooga is perceived as the strongest challenger to Nashville, voters from Nashville will only vote for Nashville, because it is the leading candidate and they prefer no alternative to it. Voters from Chattanooga and Knoxville will withdraw their support from Nashville, the leading candidate, because they do not support it over Chattanooga. The new results would be:
*Memphis: 42
*Nashville: 68
*Chattanooga: 32
*Knoxville: 32If, however, Memphis were perceived as the strongest challenger, voters from Memphis would withdraw their votes from Nashville, whereas voters from Chattanooga and Knoxville would support Nashville over Memphis. The results would then be:
*Memphis: 42
*Nashville: 58
*Chattanooga: 32
*Knoxville: 32The mathematics of approval voting lend it to some manipulation and tactical voting. As each vote counts as one vote and the winner is the one with the highest total, each vote equally helps the candidate/issue (city in this example) selected win. Because of this, voters are more likely to only vote for their favorite. Because approval voting has not been used much for real elections, this phenomenon is not well documented.
Range voting (scored ratings)
:"Winner: Nashville"
Range voting (also called ratings summation, or average voting, or cardinal ratings, or 0-99 voting, or the score system or point system) is a voting system used for single-seat elections in which votes are graded.In this example, suppose that voters each decided to grant from 1 to 10 points to each city such that their most liked choice got 10 points, and least liked choice got 1 point, with the intermediate choices getting 5 points and 2 points.
Voter from/ City Choice Memphis Nashville Chattanooga Knoxville Total Memphis 420 (42 × 10) 26 (26 × 1) 15 (15 × 1) 17 (17 × 1) 478 Nashville 210 (42 × 5) 260 (26 × 10) 30 (15 × 2) 34 (17 × 2) 534 Chattanooga 84 (42 × 2) 130 (26 × 5) 150 (15 × 10) 85 (17 × 5) 449 Knoxville 42 (42 × 1) 52 (26 × 2) 75 (15 × 5) 170 (17 × 10) 339 Nashville wins, but Memphis would have won if the voters from Memphis had reduced the points they gave Nashville from 5 down to 1 and all other votes had remained the same. Voters from Chattanooga or Knoxville could restore Nashville to first place over Memphis if they raised the points they gave Nashville from 2 up to 10.
Multiple winners
Although the example is about choosing a state capital, it can also be used to consider some multiple winner elections.
Block voting
With
block voting , for one vote each and one winner, Memphis wins, as in plurality voting.With two votes each, and two winners, Nashville and Chattanooga win as the support is (adding up to 200)
* Memphis: 42 total votes
* Nashville: 68 total votes (wins)
* Chattanooga: 58 total votes (wins)
* Knoxville: 32 total votes.With three votes each, and three winners, Nashville, Chattanooga and Knoxville win, as the support is (adding up to 300)
* Memphis: 42 total votes
* Nashville: 100 total votes (wins)
* Chattanooga: 100 total votes (wins)
* Knoxville: 58 total votes (wins).So Memphis wins if there is one winner but loses if there are two or three winners.
Limited voting
With
limited voting , voters have multiple votes, but fewer than the number of winners. If for example voters have two votes each and the top three cities are chosen then Memphis, Nashville and Chattanooga win as the support is (adding up to 200)
* Memphis: 42 total votes (wins)
* Nashville: 68 total votes (wins)
* Chattanooga: 58 total votes (wins)
* Knoxville: 32 total votes.ingle non-transferable vote
In the
single non-transferable vote system, the cities in rank order of support are Memphis, Nashville, Knoxville and finally Chattanooga: so with one winner Memphis wins; with two winners Memphis and Nashville win; and with three winners Memphis, Nashville and Knoxville win. A city which wins an election will also win if the number of winners is increased.ingle transferable vote
In the
single transferable vote system with just one winner, Knoxville wins, as with instant-runoff voting. The quota is about 51%:
*Round 1: No city meets the quota so Chattanooga is eliminated.
*Round 2: Chattanooga votes transfer to Knoxville raising Knoxville's support to 32%. No city meets the quota so Nashville is eliminated.
*Round 3: Nashville's votes transfer to Knoxville raising Knoxville's support to 58%. Knoxville now exceeds the quota and wins.If two winners were to be selected, Memphis and Nashville would win. The quota would be about 34%:
*Round 1: Memphis exceeds the quota and wins.
*Round 2: Memphis's surplus of 8% transfers to Nashville raising Nashville's support to 34%. Nashville now meets the quota and takes the second winning place.If three winners were to be selected, Memphis, Nashville and Chattanooga would win. The quota would be about 26%:
*Round 1: Memphis exceeds the quota and wins. Nashville meets the quota and wins.
*Round 2: Memphis's surplus of 16% transfers to Chattanooga raising Chattanooga's support to 31%. Chattanooga now exceeds the quota and takes the third winning place.So Knoxville wins if there is one winner but loses if there are two or three winners.
ee also
*
E-democracy
*Electoral reform
*Poll
*Social choice theory
*Social Choice and Individual Values
*Sortition , decision by randomness
*Table of voting systems by nation
*Vote counting system
*Voting machine
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.
Voting system — For other uses, see Voting system (disambiguation). Part of the Politics series Electoral methods … Wikipedia
India — /in dee euh/, n. 1. Hindi, Bharat. a republic in S Asia: a union comprising 25 states and 7 union territories; formerly a British colony; gained independence Aug. 15, 1947; became a republic within the Commonwealth of Nations Jan. 26, 1950.… … Universalium
Mexico — • Situated at the extreme point of the North American continent, bounded on the north by the United States, on the east by the Gulf of Mexico, the Caribbean Sea, British Honduras, and Guatemala, and on the south and west by the Pacific Ocean… … Catholic encyclopedia
United States — a republic in the N Western Hemisphere comprising 48 conterminous states, the District of Columbia, and Alaska in North America, and Hawaii in the N Pacific. 267,954,767; conterminous United States, 3,022,387 sq. mi. (7,827,982 sq. km); with… … Universalium
Europe, history of — Introduction history of European peoples and cultures from prehistoric times to the present. Europe is a more ambiguous term than most geographic expressions. Its etymology is doubtful, as is the physical extent of the area it designates.… … Universalium
France — /frans, frahns/; Fr. /frddahonns/, n. 1. Anatole /ann nann tawl /, (Jacques Anatole Thibault), 1844 1924, French novelist and essayist: Nobel prize 1921. 2. a republic in W Europe. 58,470,421; 212,736 sq. mi. (550,985 sq. km). Cap.: Paris. 3.… … Universalium
Germany — /jerr meuh nee/, n. a republic in central Europe: after World War II divided into four zones, British, French, U.S., and Soviet, and in 1949 into East Germany and West Germany; East and West Germany were reunited in 1990. 84,068,216; 137,852 sq.… … Universalium
Law, Crime, and Law Enforcement — ▪ 2006 Introduction Trials of former heads of state, U.S. Supreme Court rulings on eminent domain and the death penalty, and high profile cases against former executives of large corporations were leading legal and criminal issues in 2005.… … Universalium
Australia — /aw strayl yeuh/, n. 1. a continent SE of Asia, between the Indian and the Pacific oceans. 18,438,824; 2,948,366 sq. mi. (7,636,270 sq. km). 2. Commonwealth of, a member of the Commonwealth of Nations, consisting of the federated states and… … Universalium
Business and Industry Review — ▪ 1999 Introduction Overview Annual Average Rates of Growth of Manufacturing Output, 1980 97, Table Pattern of Output, 1994 97, Table Index Numbers of Production, Employment, and Productivity in Manufacturing Industries, Table (For Annual… … Universalium