- Arnold Harberger
Infobox Scientist
image_width = 150px
name = Arnold Harberger
birth_date = Birth date and age|1924|7|27
birth_place =Newark, New Jersey ,U.S.
death_date =
death_place =
residence = U.S.
nationality = American
field =Economics
work_institution = UCLA 1984-University of Chicago 1953-91Johns Hopkins University 1949-53
alma_mater =University of Chicago MA 1947, PhD 1950Johns Hopkins University BA 1943
doctoral_advisor =Lloyd Metzler
doctoral_students =Gregory Chow Robert Lucas, Jr. Zvi Griliches Marc Nerlove
known_for =Public finance
prizes =
religion =
footnotes =Arnold C. Harberger (b.
July 27 ,1924 inNewark, New Jersey ) is an American economist.Harberger's Triangle , widely used inwelfare economics , is named after him.Life
Hargerger did a B.A. in economics at
Johns Hopkins University . He completed an MA in international relations in 1947 and a Ph.D. in economics in 1950, both at theUniversity of Chicago . After teaching at Johns Hopkins, Harberger returned to Chicago to teach, full time 1953-82, and part time 1984-91. Since 1984 he has had an affiliation with theUniversity of California-Los Angeles . Harberger is married to a Chilean and speaks fluent Spanish. He is widely acknowledged as being a great supporter of his students and has championed them in their careers.Work
Harberger's PhD thesis, written under
Lloyd Metzler , was on international macroeconomic theory, but his academic reputation is primarily based on his work inpublic finance , the economics of taxation.In 1954, Harberger published an article claiming that the welfare cost of monopoly in the American economy was unlikely to exceed 0.1% of American GDP. Harberger devised a rough estimate of the
deadweight loss from monopoly, namely the producer andconsumer's surplus that fails to materialize under monopoly. In the standard diagram used to teach the theory of monopoly, this loss corresponds to the area of a triangle. Such triangles are now named in his honor, especially since Harberger (1971), a classic expository article on applied welfare economics that clearly highlighted the role of deadweight loss.Harberger's estimate assumed that the elasticity of demand for all output was -1, when no monopolist will ever set a price in that region of the demand curve for his output. Later calculations taking this and other criticisms of Harberger's analysis into account showed that the welfare loss from monopoly was unlikely to exceed 0.5% of GDP. A subtler critique is a point
Richard Posner raised in 1975, namely that the welfare cost of monopoly should include all monopoly profits as well as Harberger's triangle.Harberger (1962) is the classic economic analysis of the corporate income tax. Harberger's key insight was to see that the classic
Heckscher-Ohlin model of international trade with tariffs could be recast as a general equilibrium model for one country with two sectors, one made up of incorporated firms subject to the corporate income tax, and the other sector consisting of unincorporated firms. Harberger's work spawned a whole literature using trade theory to address questions in public finance.Both the incorporated and unincorporated sectors make 2 goods, using the same
constant returns to scale Cobb-Douglas technology. The factors of production are labour and capital. Labour is free to move between the two sectors, so that labor is paid the same in both sectors. Installed capital is not free to move, but new capital (investment) goes to where it enjoys the highest return. All consumers have the same Cobb-Douglas utility functions. The corporate income tax is a flat tax on the return to corporate capital. The flat rate may differ from the top rate of personal income tax, the marginal tax rate to which the return on unincorporated capital is subject. There is no integration of the corporate andpersonal income taxes, so that any dividends are taxed twice.Harberger's conclusion, seen as surprising at the time, was that the corporate income tax lowers the after-tax marginal product of all owners of capital equally. Since labor and new capital were free to costlessly change sectors, each factor got paid exactly its "value of marginal product" and because
constant returns to scale are assumed, the total payment to each factor exactly equals the total value the factor contributed. Therefore if the corporate sector were taxed and the other not taxed, the output of the taxed sector would shrink so as to equilibrate the marginal revenue products of both capital and labor to higher pre-tax levels. Hence the after-tax payments to each factor of production would be the same in both sectors. Net after-tax prices of goods in the taxed sector would go up since the total spent by consumers on the output of each sector remain unchanged, since we assume Cobb-Douglas utility.An implication of Harberger's analysis is that the corporate income tax lowers the steady state capital-labor ratio, and hence real GDP per capita and the standard of living. Feldstein and others have argued that a corporate income tax in the range of 35%-50% could lower steady state real GDP per capita by 15% to 40%; these findings are not canonical.
The incidence of the corporate tax falls not only on the owners of corporations, but on all owners of all firms, whether incorporated or not, because the corporate income tax changes the prices of all capital goods. While Harberger's analysis has become more or less canonical in academic economics, Harberger has distanced himself from it in recent years.
A number of Harberger's students were Latin Americans who became high level civil servants in their native countries, especially Chile and Argentina. Harberger acquired a considerable consulting practice as an economic adviser to Latin America. This work was not free of controversy, because Harberger did not shy away from giving economic advice to Chile while it was ruled by
Pinochet .References
* 1962, "The Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax," "Journal of Political Economy 70": 215.
* 1971, "Three Theorems of Applied Welfare Economics," "Journal of Economic Literature 3": .
* 1974. "Taxation and Welfare". Little, Brown.
* 1976 "Economic Genocide in Chile" Andre Gunder Frank (pamphlet)* van Overtveldt, Johan, 2007. "The Chicago School". Chicago: Agate.
ee also
*
Chicago Boys External links
* [http://www.econ.ucla.edu/harberger/ Arnold Harberger's UCLA web page]
* [http://minneapolisfed.org/pubs/region/99-03/harberger.cfm Interview] at the Minneapolis Fed, March 1999
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.