- Race to the bottom
In
government regulation , a race to the bottom is a phenomenon that is said to occur when competition between nations or states (overinvestment capital, for example) leads to the progressive dismantling of regulatory standards. This theory, also calleddownward harmonization , states that this reduction of regulation, welfare, taxes, and trade barriers will increase poverty, and drive the poor to the few remaining areas that retain protections. In the end this theory argues that this will force the last remaining states to drop their protections in order to survive.History
The term "Race to the bottom" was coined by
US Supreme Court JusticeLouis Brandeis in the 1933 case,Ligget Co. v. Lee (288 U.S. 517, 558-559). cite book
last =Kelly
first =John E.
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =2002
title =Industrial Relations: critical perspectives on business and management
publisher =Routledge
location =UK
id =ISBN 0-415-22986-3p. 192 ] cite book
last =Meisel
first =Nicolas
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =
title =Governance Culture and Development: A Different Perspective on Corporate Governance
publisher =Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
location =
id =ISBN 92-64-01727-5 p. 41] cite book
last =Schram
first =Sanford F.
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =2000
title =After Welfare: The Culture of Postindustrial Social Policy
publisher =NYU Press
location =
id =ISBN 0-8147-9755-5 p. 91] In the late 19th centuryJoint-stock company control was being liberated in Europe. Countries engaged in competitive liberal legislation to allow local companies to compete. This liberalization reached Spain in 1869, Germany in 1870, Belgium in 1873, and Italy in 1883. The same effect was happening in the US, when states were competing to attract firms to incorporate in their state--competition described by some of the time as "race to efficiency", and others, such as JusticeLouis Brandeis , as the "race to the bottom".Schram explains that the term "race to the bottom":
In 1932 Brandeis also coined the term “laboratories of democracy” in the
New State Ice Company v. Liebmann case (285 U.S. 262, 311). With these two opinions Brandeis helped develop what were to become controlling metaphors for thinking about the potential and pitfalls of federalism.Basis in game theory
Races to the bottom can be described in
game theory by theprisoner's dilemma game. This is an exercise where the optimal outcome for the entire group of participants results from cooperation of the participants, but is put in danger by the fact that the optimal outcome for each individual is to not cooperate while the others do cooperate.An economic example of racing to the bottom is
tax competition between nations. Each nation may see benefits in having a high tax on corporate profits in order to promote income equality between investors and the working class. However, nations can benefit individually with a lower corporate tax rate relative to the other nations in order to attract businesses away from the other nations. This action would hurt all nations except the one that undercut the others. In order to maintain the equilibrium, each of the other nations would have to lower their corporate tax rates to match the "defector" (the nation that first lowered the tax rate). The end result is that each nation adopts a lower corporate tax rate (which is less favorable in terms of promoting income equality). The optimal option for everyone would be an agreement to maintaintax harmonization .Occurrence and limitations
Occurrence of races to the bottom is mitigated by the costs of moving investment and production between countries, by persistence of
comparative advantage s (such as skilled workforces, infrastructure or proximity to natural resources), and by the presence of minimum standards, rules or conventions which prevent them.Races to the bottom can also occur between the states or administrative regions within nations, which often seek to attract businesses and jobs on the basis of a favourable regulatory environment. The extent of such intra-national races is limited by the power and inclination of central national governments to act against them.
In practice, races to the bottom appear to be rarer than some critics of
globalisation have feared. States are often willing to maintain regulatory regimes even if they lose certain investment or industries as a result.Implications
In its early stages, a race to the bottom can be of immediate benefit to all parties, in situations where laws are genuinely and inefficiently burdensome.
In general, however, these contests regularly work to undermine the ability of governments to enforce
labor standards such asworkers' compensation , or to raisetaxation in order to fund social services and correct externalities (such as pollution and social degradation).According to this theory, races to the bottom between sovereign states can also undermine democratic
accountability , since the elected governments are no longer economically capable of passing legislation which enforces environmental or labour protections that are more stringent than those current in neighbouring countries.Some economists believe, however, that "races to the bottom" can help ameliorate
poverty , for if businesses can operate for less money, they can cutprice s while maintaining theirprofit margin sFact|date=April 2008.Causes and responses
The dismantling of
tariff s and other trade barriers, facilitated by the rules set within theWorld Trade Organization , and encouraged (in the global South) by US influence through theWorld Bank and theInternational Monetary Fund , may have removed an important constraint on races-to-the-bottom; without protected domestic industries, countries are more dependent on liquid investment capital. One solution to this problem is to employ international fora, such as the WTO, to set satisfactory environmental and labor rules at a global level.Another suggested method for avoiding races to the bottom is
moral purchasing . Moral purchasing can influence decisions at the level of individual buyers, or it can involve forbidding or applying heavytax, tariff and trade sanctions to nations that permit the export of offensive goods, re-directing revenues raised from such tax or tariff to combating abuses.Standards-based tariffs represent another way to halt a race to the bottom. While conventional tariffs are designed to protect jobs in a particular industry or sector of the economy, standards-based tariffs are designed to protect country-wide standards such as labour standards and environmental standards. With standards-based tariffs, a product imported from a country with low labour and environmental standards will face a high tariff, while a product imported from a country with labour and environmental standards equal to or higher than the domestic standards will face no tariff. For producers, such tariffs remove the incentive to move a factory to the country with the lowest wage rates and most permissive pollution laws. For governments, such tariffs provide an incentive to raise their standards upwards, in order to gain entry into new export markets. For workers, such tariffs prevent the wage rate from falling down to the wage rate of the lowest country in the trading group. For consumers, such tariffs would undoubtedly raise prices since cheap imported goods from low-labour-standard countries would be replaced with expensive domestically produced goods (this is the price of protecting domestic labour and environmental standards).
Note that since standards-based tariffs only restrain exports from poorer countries to wealthier countries, global implementation would result in free trade between the world's wealthiest countries. Also note that such tariffs would result in free trade between newly-developing countries that had similar labour and environmental standards.
Corporate Law
In the US legal academia, corporate law is conventionally said to be the product of a "race" among states to attract incorporations by making their corporate laws attractive to those who choose where to incorporate. Given that it has long been possible to incorporate in one state while doing business primarily in other states, US states have rarely been able or willing to use law tied to where a firm is incorporated to regulate or constrain corporations or those who run them. (However, US states have long regulated corporations with other laws (e.g., environmental laws, employment laws) that are not tied to where a firm is incorporated, but are based on where a firm does business.)
From the "race" to attract incorporations,
Delaware has emerged as the winner, at least among publicly traded corporations. The corporatefranchise tax accounts for between 15 and 20 % of the state's budget.There is a longstanding debate whether US
corporate law is subject to a race to the bottom or arace to the top . At the heart of the debate lies the question whether the US states' corporate laws are desirable in their present state or not. Important proponents of the "race to the top" perspective have been Ralph Winter,Roberta Romano , Frank Easterbrook andDaniel Fischel . The "race to the bottom" perspective started with an article byWilliam Cary in 1974 and has been developed further most importantly byHarvard Law School ProfessorLucian Bebchuk . However, according to a critical [http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center/corporate_governance/papers/No432.03.Roe.pdf appraisal] byHarvard Law School Professor Mark Roe, the debate is misconceived, since Delaware's law has been shaped less by competition with other states than by pressure from the federal level. The empirical evidence does not conclusively support any of the theories.In Europe, regulatory competition has long been prevented by the
real seat doctrine prevailing inprivate international law of manyEU and EEA member countries, which essentially required companies to be incorporated in the state where their main office was located. However, in a series of cases between 1999 and 2003 (Centros, Überseering, Inspire Art), theEuropean Court of Justice has forced member states to recognize companies chartered in other member states, which is likely to foster regulatory competition inEuropean company law .Rhetoric
The phrase 'race to the bottom' is used sometimes in a pejorative context by those opposed to
globalization and those supportingfair trade companies.An example: in response to reports that British supermarkets had cut the price of
banana s, and by implication had squeezed revenues of banana-growing, developing nations, Alistair Smith, international co-coordinator ofBanana Link , said "The British supermarkets are leading a race to the bottom. Jobs are being lost and producers are having to pay less attention to social and environmental agreements.""The Times " Business Section, Monday 7th December 2003]"Race to the top"
The phrase race to the top was coined in response to "race to the bottom" [cite journal
first =Kagan
last =Kocaoglu
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =2008
month =March
title = A Comparative Bibliography: Regulatory Competition on Corporate Law
journal = (Georgetown University Law Center Working Paper)
volume =
issue =
pages =
id =
url = http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1103644] .It is a process by which competition leads to the progressive improvement of goods and services provided to consumers. One example of the "race to the top" is the success of the computer industry in creating ever-faster and more powerful computers.
Notes
Further reading
*cite journal
first =Kagan
last =Kocaoglu
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =2008
month =March
title = A Comparative Bibliography: Regulatory Competition on Corporate Law
journal = (Georgetown University Law Center Working Paper)
volume =
issue =
pages =
id =
url = http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1103644
*cite journal
first =David
last =Bacon
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =2003
month =February 03
title =Anti-China Campaign Hides Maquiladora Wage Cuts
journal =zmag.org
volume =
issue =
pages =
id =
url =http://www.zmag.org/content/showarticle.cfm?ItemID=2949
*cite journal
first =Robin
last =Hahnel
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =2000
month =March
title =Houston, We Have A Problem Challenging globalization
journal =zmag.org
volume =
issue =
pages =
id =
url =http://www.zmag.org/ZMag/articles/march2000hahnel.htm
doi =10.1021/jo9919207
*cite journal
first =Edward L.
last =Hudgins
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =
month =
title =The Myth of the Race to the Bottom
journal =CATO institute
volume =
issue =
pages =
id =
url =http://www.freetrade.org/pubs/freetotrade/chap3.html
*cite journal
first =Sheila
last =McClear
authorlink =
coauthors =
year =2005
month =March
title =Race to Bottom for Garment Workers
journal =Z magazine
volume =18
issue =3
pages =
id =
url =http://zmagsite.zmag.org/Mar2005/mcclear0305.html
format =dead link|date=June 2008 – [http://scholar.google.co.uk/scholar?hl=en&lr=&q=author%3AMcClear+intitle%3ARace+to+Bottom+for+Garment+Workers&as_publication=Z+magazine&as_ylo=2005&as_yhi=2005&btnG=Search Scholar search]
* cite web
title =Is Globalization Causing A 'Race To The Bottom' In Environmental Standards?
work =worldbank.org
url = http://www1.worldbank.org/economicpolicy/globalization/documents/AssessingGlobalizationP4.pdf
accessdate=2006-09-05
*cite web
title =A "Race to the Bottom" Globilisation and China's labour standards
work = Australian National University
url =http://rspas.anu.edu.au/~anita/pdf/AChancp461.pdf
accessdate=2006-09-05
Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.