Generalized game theory

Generalized game theory

Generalized game theory is an extension of game theory to incorporate social theory concepts such as norm, value, belief, role, social relationship, and institution. The theory was developed by Tom R. Burns and has not had great influence beyond his immediate associates. The theory seeks to address certain perceived limitations of game theory by formulating a theory of rules and to incorporate more robust approach to socio-phsychological phenomena.

In generalized game theory, games are conceptualized as rule complexes, which is a set containing rules and/or other rule complexes. However, the rules may be imprecise, inconsistent, and even dynamic. The ways in which the rules may be changed is developed within the context of generalized game theory based on the principle of game transformation. This allows the rules themselves to be analyzed in complex ways, and thus the model more closely represents relationships and institutions discussed in the social sciences. These types of games are sometimes called open games, that is, games which are open to transformation. Games which have specified, fixed players, fixed preference structures, fixed optimization procedures, and fixed action alternatives and outcomes are called closed games.

Along the same lines, generalized game theory stresses the cultural institutional approach to game conceptualization and analysis (Baumgartner et al, 1975, see Burns, 2005). This is in contrast to conceptualization of games consisting of actors which are autonomous utility maximizers. Further, the modeling of the actors themselves in generalized game theory is especially open to the use of concepts such as incomplete information and bounded rationality.

Proponents of generalized game theory have advocated the application of the theory to agent-based modeling, fuzzy games, social evolution, and new institutionalism, among others.

Principles

Judgment in generalized game theory

A key aspect of actors decision making in generalized game theory is based on the concept of judgment. Several types of judgment could be relevant, for instance value judgment, factual judgment, and action judgment. In the case of action judgment, the actor seeks to take the course of action offered by the rules of the game which most closely fit the values held by the actor (where the values are a sub-rule complex of the game). Even the method by which the actor calculates closeness of fit can be controlled by the actors values (such as an actor might use a more speedy algorithm, or a more far-sighted one). The each actor has a judgment operator by which the actor can create a preference order of the perceived qualities of possible outcomes based on satisfying the condition that the qualities of the outcomes can be roughly said to be sufficiently similar to the qualities of the actors primary values or norms. Thus, in generalized game theory, each actor's judgment calculus includes the institutional context of the game (Burns, 2005).

General game solutions

A general or common game solution is a strategy or interaction order for the agents which satisfies or realizes the relevant norms and values of the players. This should lead to a state that is acceptable by the game players, and is not necessarily a normative equilibrium, but represents the "best result attainable under the circumstances" (Burns, 2005). Solutions may be reached through a sequence of proposed alternatives, and when the actors find the ultimate solution acceptable, the proposed solutions may be said to be convergent. Roszkowska and Burns (2002) showed that not every game has a common solution, and that divergent proposals may arise. This may result in a no equilibrium being found, and stems from dropping the assumption for the existence of a Nash equilibrium that the game that the game be finite or that the game have complete information. Another possibility is the existence of a rule which allows a dictator to force an equilibrium. The rules which make up the norms of the game are one way of resolving the problem of choosing between multiple equilibria, wuch as those arising in the so-called folk theorem.

Example: prisoner's dilemma

In the example of the two-player prisoner's dilemma, for instance, proponents of generalized game theory are critical of the rational Nash equilibrium wherein both actors defect because rational actors would be predisposed to work out coordinating mechanisms in order to achieve optimum outcomes. Although these mechanisms are not usually included in the rules of the game, generalized game theorists argue that they do exist in real life situations the prisoner's dilemma seeks to model. This is because there always exists a social relationship between the players characterized by rules and rule complexes. This relationship may be one of, for instance, solidarity (which results in the Pareto optimal outcome), adversary (which results in the Nash equilibrium), or even hierarchy (by which one actor sacrifices their own good for the others benefit). Some values, such as pure rivalry, are seen as nonstable because both actors would seek asymmetric gain, and thus would need to either transform the game or seek another value to attempt to satisfy. If no communication mechanism is given (as is usual in the prisoner's dilemma), the social relationship between the actors is based on the actors own beliefs about the other (perhaps as another member of the human race, solidarity will be felt, or perhaps as a fellow criminal, adversary). This illustrates the principle of game transformation, which is a key element of the theory.

References

*Baumgartner, T, Buckley, W, and Burns, T R (1975) "Relational Control: The Human Structuring of Cooperation and Conflict", Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 19: 417-440
*Burns, Tom R and Roszkowska, Ewa (2005) "Generalized Game Theory: Assumptions, Principles, and Elaborations", Studies in Logic, Grammer, and Rhetoric, Vol. 8 (21)
*Roszkowska Ewa and Burns, T R (2002) Fuzzy Judgment in Bargaining Games: Diverse Patterns of Price Determination and Transaction in Buyer-Seller Exchange". Paper presented at the First World Congress of Game Theory, Bilbao, Spain, 2000. available [http://www.soc.uu.se/publications/fulltext/tb_/market-pricing-game.doc here (MSWord doc)] .


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать курсовую

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Generalized game — In computational complexity theory, a generalized game is a game that has been generalized so that it can be played on a board of any size. For example, generalized chess is the game of chess played on an n by n board, with 2 n pieces on each… …   Wikipedia

  • Dominance (game theory) — In game theory, dominance (also called strategic dominance) occurs when one strategy is better than another strategy for one player, no matter how that player s opponents may play. Many simple games can be solved using dominance.The opposite,… …   Wikipedia

  • Game complexity — Combinatorial game theory has several ways of measuring game complexity. This article describes five of them: state space complexity, game tree size, decision complexity, game tree complexity, and computational complexity. Contents 1 Measures of… …   Wikipedia

  • Social rule system theory — is an attempt to formally approach different kinds of social rule systems in a unified manner. Social rules systems include institutions such as norms, laws, regulations, taboos, customs, and a variety of related concepts and are important in the …   Wikipedia

  • Generalized geography — In computational complexity theory, generalized geography is a problem that can be proven to be PSPACE Complete.IntroductionGeography is a childs game, which is good for a long car trip, where players take turns naming cities from anywhere in the …   Wikipedia

  • Theory of everything — A theory of everything (TOE) is a putative theory of theoretical physics that fully explains and links together all known physical phenomena. Initially, the term was used with an ironic connotation to refer to various overgeneralized theories.… …   Wikipedia

  • Info-gap decision theory — is a non probabilistic decision theory that seeks to optimize robustness to failure – or opportuneness for windfall – under severe uncertainty,[1][2] in particular applying sensitivity analysis of the stability radius type[3] to perturbations in… …   Wikipedia

  • Zero–sum game — For other uses, see Zero sum (disambiguation). In game theory and economic theory, a zero sum game is a mathematical representation of a situation in which a participant s gain (or loss) of utility is exactly balanced by the losses (or gains) of… …   Wikipedia

  • Hex (board game) — Infobox Game subject name=The Game of Hex image link= image caption=A rendering of a Hex game on a 19x19 board players=2 ages=4+ setup time=1 minute playing time=15 minutes (11x11 board) complexity=Low strategy=High random chance=None… …   Wikipedia

  • War of attrition (game) — In game theory, the war of attrition is a model of aggression in which two contestants compete for a resource of value V by persisting while constantly accumulating costs over the time t that the contest lasts. The model was originally formulated …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”