Relations of production

Relations of production

Relations of production (German: "Produktionsverhältnisse") is a concept frequently used by Karl Marx in his theory of historical materialism and in Das Kapital. Beyond examining specific cases, Marx never defined the general concept exactly. It is evident, though, that it refers to all kinds of social and technical human interconnections involved in the social production and reproduction of material life. "Social" denotes belonging, group membership and co-operative activity (in Latin, 'socius' means comrade, companion or associate). "Technical" refers here to a relationship between producers and objects worked upon.

Definitions

A social relation can be defined, in the first instance, as

*a relation between individuals insofar as they belong to a group, or
*a relation between groups, or
*a relation between an individual and a group

The group could be an ethnic or kinship group, a social institution or organisation, a social class, a nation or gender etc.

A social relation is therefore not simply identical with an interpersonal relation or an individual relation, although all these types of relations presuppose each other. A social relation refers to a common social characteristic of a group of people.

"Society" for Marx is "the sum total of social relations connecting its members".

Social "relations of production" in Marx's sense refer to

*(often legally encoded) ownership & control relations pertaining to society's productive assets,
*the way people are formally and informally associated within the economic sphere of production, including as social classes,
*work relations (including household labor),
*socio-economic dependencies between people arising from the way they produce and reproduce their existence,
*the quantitative proportions of different aspects of the sphere of production, considered from the point of view of society as a whole.

The totality of social relations of production constitute the social structure of the economy, which according to Marx determine how incomes, products and assets will be distributed.

Illustration

In Das Kapital, Marx illustrates the concept of relations of production with reference to Edward Gibbon Wakefield's theory of colonisation:

In other words, the English relations of production did not exist in Australia; there was no system of property rights and legal obligations and no economic necessity compelling workers to work for their boss. The servants therefore could leave Mr Peel in order to find work or occupy free land to make a better living.

ocial/technical distinction and reification

Combined with the productive forces, the relations of production constitute a historically specific mode of production. Karl Marx contrasts the social relations of production with the technical relations of production; in the former case, it is people (subjects) who are related, in the latter case, the relation is between people and objects in the physical world they inhabit (those objects are, in the context of production, what Marx calls the "means of labor" or means of production.

However, Marx argues that with the rise of market economy, this distinction is increasingly obscured and distorted. In particular, a cash economy makes it possible to define, symbolise and manipulate relationships between things that people make in abstraction from the social & technical relations involved. Marx says this leads to the reification (thingification or "Verdinglichung") of economic relations, of which commodity fetishism is a prime example.

The marketplace seems to be a place where all people have free and equal access and freely negotiate and bargain over deals and prices on the basis of civil equality. People will buy and sell goods without really knowing where they originated or who made them. They know that objectively they depend on producers and consumers somewhere else, that this social dependency exists, but they do not know who specifically those people are or what their activities are. Market forces seem to regulate everything, but what is really behind those market forces has become obscured, because the social relationship between people or their relation with nature is expressed as a commercial relationship between things (money, commodities, capital).

Some social relations of production therefore exist in an objective, mind-independent way, not simply because they are a natural necessity for human groups, but because of the mediation of social and technical relations by commerce. In addition to creating new social and technical relations, commerce introduces a proliferation of relationships between tradeable 'things'. Not only do relationships between 'things' (commodities, prices etc.) begin to indicate and express social and technical relations, the commercial relations also begin to govern and regulate the pattern of human contact and technique.

The fact therefore that particular social relations of production acquire an objective, mind-independent existence may not be due to any natural necessity asserting itself but only to a purely social necessity: commodity exchange objectifies social relations to the point where they escape from conscious human control, and exist such that they can be recognised only by abstract thought.

Relations of production and relations of distribution

One of the theoretical problems in Marxian economics is to distinguish exactly between "relations of production" and "relations of distribution", determining the significance of each in the allocation of resources. According to the crudest and most vulgar interpretations of Das Kapital, exploitation occurs only at the point of production. Marx himself obviously did not assert this at all, he only postulated the command over the surplus labour of others as the basis of the existence of capital and its economic power.

Marx discusses the theoretical problem in two main places: the introduction to the "Grundrisse" manuscript and in chapter 51 of Das Kapital. In the "Grundrisse", where he defines the total economy to include production, circulation, distribution and consumption (similar to James Mill), he raises the following question:

He answers his own question negatively:

Disagreeing with David Ricardo, who regarded "distribution" as the proper object of study for economics, Marx argues that the mode of production largely "determines" the mode of distribution: the "source" of income & products in production, and their "distribution" among the population must be analysed within one framework:

In the last chapters of Das Kapital Vol 3, he develops the argument, defining relations of distribution as the "forms" which "express the relationships in which the total value newly produced is distributed among the owners of the various agents of production" (as income and products).

His critique of political economy in this regard was(1) that relations of production or distribution are posited as "natural and eternal" rather than as historically specific relations, (2) that forms of distribution of income and products are crucially determined by property relations pertaining to productive assets; (3) that by constantly reproducing the relations of production, the mode of production of capital also reproduces the relations of distribution corresponding to it.

Late in his life, Marx touches on the issue again:

Criticism of Marx's concept

It is frequently objected by Weberian sociologists (those in the tradition of Max Weber) that Marx paid insufficient attention to the "intersubjective" dimension of social relations, i.e. the meanings consciously attached by people to their social interactions.

However, Marx's argument is that these subjective or intersubjective meanings permit of infinite variations, and therefore cannot be the foundation for a genuine science of society. Rather, one must begin with understanding those objective interdependencies which by necessity shape and socialise human beings, i.e. those social relations which people as social beings must enter into, regardless of what they may think or wish.

In this context, the young Vladimir Lenin commented:

Quotation|Hitherto, sociologists had found it difficult to distinguish the important and the unimportant in the complex network of social phenomena (that is the root of subjectivism in sociology) and had been unable to discover any objective criterion for such a demarcation. Materialism provided an absolutely objective criterion by singling out "production relations" as thestructure of society, and by making it possible to apply to these relations that general scientific criterion of recurrence whose applicability to sociology the subjectivists denied. So long as they confined themselves to ideological social relations (i.e., such as, before taking shape, pass through mans consciousness - We are, of course, referring all the time to the consciousness of social relations and no others - they could not observerecurrence and regularity in the social phenomena of the various countries, and their science was at best only a description of these phenomena, a collection of raw material. The analysis of material social relations (i.e., of those that take shape without passing through mans consciousness: when exchanging products men enter into production relations without even realising that there is a social relation of production here)-the analysis of material social relations at once made it possible to observe recurrenceand regularity and to generalise the systems of the various countries in the single fundamental concept: social formation. It was this generalisation alone that made it possible to proceed from the description of social phenomena (and their evaluation from the standpoint of an ideal) to their strictly scientific analysis, which isolates, let us say by way of example,that which distinguishes one capitalist country from another andinvestigates that which is common to all of them... Then, however, Marx, who had expressed this hypothesis in the forties, set out to study the factual (nota bene) material. He took one of the social-economic formations- the system of commodity production-and on the basis of a vast mass of data (which he studied for not less than twenty five years) gave a most detailed analysis of the laws governing the functioning of this formation and its development.|Vladimir Lenin|What the “Friends of the People” Are and How They Fight the Social-Democrats, 1894

Another sort of criticism, from economists, consists of the observation that processes of distribution (of products and income) can to a considerable extent develop "independently" or autonomously from what happens in production, with the aid of a developed credit system.

In fact, gross distortions between value added in production, and the distribution of products and incomes, might occur - for example, as a result of underdevelopment, imperialism, state intervention, unequal exchange, fictitious capital, credit bubbles or capital gains from rising property values.

That is, a society or region might get much more or much less income than the value of what it produces.In that case, there are intermediary agencies between production and consumption influencing the allocation of resources.

Probably Marx would have acknowledged that, but he would presumably have argued that ultimately, the dissynchrony or distortion between production and distribution would cause a crisis and then a readjustment of distribution to the real structure of production relations.

ee also

*mode of production
*capitalist mode of production
*law of value

References

*Lenin, What the “Friends of the People” Are and How They Fight the Social-Democrats

*Göran Therborn, Science, Class and Society.

*Perry Anderson, In the Tracks of Historical Materialism.

*Herbert Gintis, Samuel Bowles, Robert T. Boyd and Ernst Fehr, Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life.


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужна курсовая?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Relations of production —    This is a key term in Karl Marx’s theory of historical materialism. Relations of production, or production relations, consist of relations involved in actual production and relations which arise because production creates a need for them. To… …   Historical dictionary of Marxism

  • relations of production — Once Karl Marx had concluded that what labourers sold under capitalism was not their labour but their labour power (see labour theory of value ), and so opened up a new dimension of analysis, he was able to shed his dependence on the inherited… …   Dictionary of sociology

  • relations — of production …   Dictionary of sociology

  • production —    by Marcus A. Doel   While many concepts employed by Baudrillard have a certain aura and mystique (such as integral reality and objective illusion), production is likely to strike the contemporary reader as lacklustre and humdrum. For… …   The Baudrillard dictionary

  • Relations economiques entre l'Amerique espagnole et l'Europe — Relations économiques entre l Amérique espagnole et l Europe Hernán Cortés, conquérant de l empire aztèque. Toutefois, contrairement à la légende, les richesses en or de l empire aztèque se révélèrent moins abondantes que prévues. Ce furent les… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Relations économiques entre l'amérique espagnole et l'europe — Hernán Cortés, conquérant de l empire aztèque. Toutefois, contrairement à la légende, les richesses en or de l empire aztèque se révélèrent moins abondantes que prévues. Ce furent les mines d argent du XVIIIe siècle et non l or …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Relations Iran-France — Relations entre la France et l Iran Relations entre la France et l Iran …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Relations entre l'Allemagne et la France — Relations entre l Allemagne et la France …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Relations entre la France et l'Iran — Relations entre la France et l Iran …   Wikipédia en Français

  • Relations entre la france et l'iran — Relations entre la France et l Iran …   Wikipédia en Français

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”