Amsterdamsche Wisselbank

Amsterdamsche Wisselbank

The Amsterdamsche Wisselbank or Bank of Amsterdam was an early commercial bank, vouched for by the city of Amsterdam, established in 1609.

Bank money

[
1609.]

In Renaissance Europe, the currency of small states - such as Genoa, Hamburg, Venice, and Nuremberg - consisted in large part of the currencies of neighboring nations. The foreign money, clipped and worn, lowered the value of a country's currency. A country's own freshly minted money, therefore, bore an agio, being worth more than its stock currency. Furthermore, it was melted as soon as it was released, its metallic content being worth more than its nominal value.

In order to remedy this situation, a bank was founded in 1609 under the protection of the city of Amsterdam. This bank at first received both foreign and local coinage at their real, intrinsic value, deduced a small coinage and management fee, and credited clients in its book for the remainder. This credit was known as "bank money". Being always in accord with mint standards, and always of the same value, bank money was worth more than real coinage. At the same time a new regulation was introduced; according to which all bills drawn at Amsterdam worth more than 600 guilders must be paid in bank money. This both removed all uncertainty from this bills and compelled all merchants to keep an account with the bank, which in turn occasioned a certain demand for bank money.

Bank money had several distinct advantages over other forms of money. It was secure from fire, robbery and other accidents; was backed by the city of Amsterdam; and could be paid or received by a simple transfer, avoiding both the costs of counting and the risks of conveyance. Furthermore, it was of a known, superior quality. Because of the above it bore an agio, being worth more than its nominal value. Consequentially, it was not often that clients asked for their money to be extracted from the bank. A shilling freshly minted will buy no more than a clipped and worn one. It was better for clients to sell the debt the bank owed them - their credit - at the market, earning a premium, which is the expression of the aforementioned agio.

Deposits of bullion and coin

Deposits of coin constituted but a small part of bank capital. Most of the bank's capital originated with deposits of gold and silver bullion, intrinsically of higher value as bullion was not debased, unlike most of the circulating currency.

The Bank of Amsterdam gave credit for deposits of gold and silver worth about 5 percent less than their mint price. It granted the depositor a "receipt", which allowed him to claim his deposit 6 months later, upon returning to the bank the same value of bank money for which credit was given, and payment of a fee for the keeping - a warehouse rent of sorts - worth 0.25% for silver, and 0.5% for gold. This fee could, of course, be paid every 6 months, extending the period of deposit. The difference of fees has been attributed both to the difficulty of ascertaining the purity of gold and to a wish to encourage deposits of silver, it being the standard metal of the time. If a depositor did not claim his deposit back after six months, it fell to the bank, and the depositor was left with the credit he received in compensation.

The terms of deposit were such that deposits of bullion were most commonly made when the price was somewhat lower than ordinary, and taken out again when it rose. The proportions between the "bank price" (the credit which the bank gave for deposits of bullion), the mint price, and the market price of gold bullion were always nearly the same. A person could generally sell his receipt for the difference between the mint price of bullion and the market price. As a receipt was nearly always worth something, it was only rarely that deposits were allowed to fall to the bank through the expiration of receipts (which means the depositor neither paid additional keeping fee nor removed his deposit from the bank). This happened more frequently with regard to gold, due to its higher keeping fee.

The bank also took in coin, granting credit and receipts in exchange, and charging 0.25% for the keeping. These receipts were often of no value, however, and the deposit was allowed to fall to the bank.

The bank maintained it did not lend any of the bullion deposited in it, not even that part for which the receipts expired, and which could not generally be claimed.

Receipts

When a holder of a receipt found himself in need of coinage, he could sell his receipt. Alternatively, when a holder of bank money found himself in need of bullion, he could buy a receipt. Receipts and credit were thus freely bought and sold. When a holder of a receipt wished to take out the bullion for which it stood, he had to purchase enough bank credit to do so. The holder of a receipt, when he purchased bank money, purchased the power of taking out a quantity of bullion, of which the mint price is five per cent above the bank price. The agio of five per cent therefore, which he commonly paid for it, was paid not for an imaginary but for a real value. The owner of bank money, when he purchased a receipt, purchased the power of taking out a quantity of bullion of which the market price is commonly from two to three per cent above the mint price. The price of the receipt, and the price of the bank money, made up between them the full value of the bullion.

The bank allowed no withdrawal except by means of a receipt. There was, however, more bank money available than the combined value of all receipts - because some receipts have been allowed to expire, but the bank money, or credit, remained in the bank's books. In times of peace, a client who wished to withdraw his deposit had no trouble purchasing a receipt and making a withdrawal. In times of distress, however, as during the French invasion in 1672, the price or receipts could be pushed upwards by demand.

Bank fees

While this was not its original aim, the Bank of Amsterdam proved profitable to the city which provided for it. In addition to the keeping fee mentioned above, each person, upon first opening an account, paid a fee of ten guilders; and three guilders three stivers for each additional account. Two stivers were paid for each transaction, excepting those of less than three hundred guilders, for which six stivers were paid, in order to discourage the multiplicity of small transactions. A person who neglected to balance his account twice in the year forfeited twenty-five guilders. A person who ordered a transfer for more than is upon his account, was obliged to pay three per cent for the sum overdrawn. The bank made further profit by selling foreign coin and bullion which fell to it by the expiration of receipts, and by selling bank money at five percent agio, and buying it as four percent. These sources of revenue were more than enough to pay for the wages of bank officers, and defraying the expense of management.

External links

* [http://www.adamsmith.org/smith/won/won-b4-c3-pt-1-digression.html Adam Smith - An Inquiry into the Nature And Causes of the Wealth of Nations - CHAPTER III - PART I - Digression concerning Banks of Deposit, Particularly concerning that of Amsterdam]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем сделать НИР

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Banque d'Amsterdam — La Amsterdamsche Wisselbank ou banque d’Amsterdam est une des premières banques de dépôt européennes. Créée en 1609 avec la garantie et l’accord des États de Hollande, c est une banque publique placée sous le contrôle de la municipalité de la… …   Wikipédia en Français

  • bank — bank1 /bangk/, n. 1. a long pile or heap; mass: a bank of earth; a bank of clouds. 2. a slope or acclivity. 3. Physical Geog. the slope immediately bordering a stream course along which the water normally runs. 4. a broad elevation of the sea… …   Universalium

  • Financial history of the Dutch Republic — describes the history of the interrelated development of financial institutions in the Dutch Republic. The rapid economic development of the country after the Dutch Revolt in the years 1585 1620, described in Economic History of the Netherlands… …   Wikipedia

  • History of banking — The first banks were the merchants of the ancient world that made loans to farmers and traders that carried goods between cities. The first records of such activity dates back to around 2000 BC in Assyria and Babylonia. Later, in ancient Greece… …   Wikipedia

  • Amsterdamer Wechselbank — Das alte Rathaus von Amsterdam, in dem 1609 die Wisselbank gegründet wurde. Ölgemälde von Pieter Janszoon Saenredam aus dem Jahr 1657. Die Amsterdamer Wechselbank (ndl: Amsterdamsche Wisselbank) war die erste städtische Wechselbank in Westeuropa …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Амстердамский банк — О частном коммерческом банке, основанном в 1871 году, см. Amsterdamsche Bank …   Википедия

  • Commercial Revolution — The Commercial Revolution was a period of European economic expansion, colonialism, and mercantilism which lasted from approximately the 16th century until the early 18th century. It was succeeded in the mid 18th century by the Industrial… …   Wikipedia

  • Economic History of the Netherlands (1500 - 1815) — The Economic History of the Netherlands (1500 1815), is the history of an economy that some consider to be the first modern economy, continuously existing to this day. It covers the period from the time in which the geographic area currently… …   Wikipedia

  • Банки — I в современном экономическом строе Б. являются высшей формой кредитного посредничества и важнейшими органами вексельного и денежного обращения. Цель банковой деятельности: во первых, создать систему кредита (см. это сл.), которая обеспечивала бы …   Энциклопедический словарь Ф.А. Брокгауза и И.А. Ефрона

  • Hamburger Bank — Die Hamburger Bank bestand vom 2. März 1619 bis zum 31. Dezember 1875. Sie wurde vom Rat der Stadt gegründet, um als Wechselstube, Girobank und Kreditbank auf Silberbasis für die ansässigen Kaufleute zu dienen. Nach längeren Verhandlungen… …   Deutsch Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”